Skip to main content

Full text of "Appreciation and interest: a study of the influence of monetary appreciation and depreciation on the rate of interest with applications to the bimetallic controversy and the theory of interest"

See other formats


Publications 

OF  THE 

American   Economic   Association 
Vol.  XI.    No.  4.  Pages  331-442. 

Appreciation  and  Interest 


A  STUDY  OF  THE  INFIvUENCE  OF  MONETARY  APPRECIA- 
TION  AND   depreciation   ON  THE  RATE  OF  INTER- 
EST,   WITH   APPLICATIONS    TO    THE   BIMETALLIC 
CONTROVERSY  AND  THE  THEORY  OF  INTEREST. 

BY 

IRVING   FISHER, 

Assistant  Professor  of  Political  Science  in  Yale  University. 


AUGUST,  1896. 


PUBLISHED  FOR  THE 

American  Economic  Association 

BY  The  Macmii,lan  Company 

NEW  YORK 

LONDON  :  SWAN  SONNENSCHEIN  &  CO. 


Hi 


^ta--,.*/api^ 


Q- 


537 


Copyright  1896  by 
American  Economic  Association 


PRESS  OF 

Andrus  &  Church, 
ithaca,  n.  y. 


^ 


APPRECIATION 

AND 

INTEREST. 


Digitized  by  the  Internet  Arciiive 
in  2010  with  funding  from 
The  Library  of  Congress 


http://www.archive.org/details/appreciationinteOOfish 


CONTENTS. 


Part  I.     Thkory. 

PAGE. 

Chapter  I.     Introduction. 

li.  Does  appreciation  necessarily  aggravate  debts?  .    ...  i 

§2.  Efforts  to  find  a  "just"  standard i 

I  3.  Invariability  of  standard  not  essential 3 

I  4.  Bearing  of  the  rate  of  interest  on  the  subject  ....  3 

Chapter  II.     One  year  contracts. 

I  I.  Foreseen  and  unforeseen  appreciation  or  depreciation,  6 

I  2.  One  year  contract,  numerical  illustration 6 

I  3.  Formula  connecting  interest  and  appreciation  ....  8 

§4.  Money  as  standard  and  as  medium 11 

Chapter  III.    More  than  one  year. 

I  I.  Confusion  in  separating  interest  and  principal  ....  12 

I  2.  Compound  interest,  five  years 12 

?  3.  General  formula I3 

I  4.  Partial  payments,  seven  years i4 

I  5.  General  formula 16 

I  6.  Special  case • ^^ 

Chapter  IV.     Present  value. 

I  I.  Different  modes  of  payment  do  not  aflfect  present  value,  19 
I  2.  Illustration  when  interest  is  paid  annually  and  princi- 
pal redeemed  at  maturity 20 

I  3.  Case  of  perpetual  annuity 21 

^  4.  Formula ^^ 

Chapter  V.     Varying  rates  of  appreciation. 

I  I.  Numerical  illustration 23 

§  2.  Average  rate  of  interest 24 

?  3.  Formula  for  varying  rate  of  interest 26 

^  4.  Formula  for  average  rate  of  interest 26 

I  5.  Formula  for  average  rate  of  appreciation 28 

I  6.  Practical  application 28 

Chapter  VI.     Zero  and  negative  interest. 

I  I.  Limits  to  rates  of  interest  and  appreciation 3° 

I  2.  Effect  of  hoarding 3^ 

I  3.  Negative  interest  possible 32 

I  4.  Investment  not  necessarily  checked  by  zero  interest  .  33 


vi                                           Contents  [338 
Part  II.     Facts. 

Chapter  VII.     Introduction. 

§  I.  Objections 35 

§  2.  Existence  of  foresight  in  general 36 

Chapter  VIII.     Gotd  atid  paper. 

§  I.  General  evidence 38 

^  2.  United  States  currency  and  coin  bonds 39 

f  3.  Extent  of  foresight  in  gold  premium 41 

?  4.  Dangers  of  preceding  method 44 

Chapter  IX.     Gotd  and  stiver. 

?  I.  India  "rupee  paper"  and  gold  bonds 46 

I  2.  Extent  of  foresight  in  Indian  exchange 49 

§3.  Upper  limit  of  gold  borrower's  loss  in  England  .    .    .  51 

^  4.  Bearing  of  a  rupee  debt  on  Indian  finance 52 

Chapter  X.    Money  and  commodities. 

§  I.  Difficulties  in  comparing  successive  periods 54 

I  2.  Rate  of  interest  as  related  to  high  and   low  prices  .  54 
§  3.  Rate  of  interest  as  related  to  rising  and  falling  prices 

in  England 56 

§  4.  Rate  of  interest  as  related  to  rising  and  falling  prices 

in  Germany,  France,  and  the  United  States  ....  60 
§  5.  Rate  of  interest  as  related  to  rising  and  falling  prices 

in  silver  standard  countries 63 

^  6.  Measurement  of  foresight  for  short  periods 66 

I  7.   Error  of  Jevons,  Price,  and  others 67 

^  S.  Measurement  of  foresight  for  long  periods,  in  England  70 

I  9.  Lower  limit  of  borrower's  loss  in  England 71 

§  10.  Loss  on  contracts  made  before  1873,  ^'^  England  ...  73 

§11.  Measurement  of  foresight  for  long  periods,  in  America,  74 
§  12.  Theory  as  to  mode  of  adjusting  rate  of  interest  to 

price  movements 75 

I  13.  Credit  cycles 76 

Part  III.     Applications. 

Chapter  XI.     The  bimetallic  controversy. 

§1.  Magnitude  of  debtor's  loss 80 

§  2.  Index  numbers 81 

?  3.  Bimetallism  could  not  correct  losses 82 

§  4.  Bimetallism  would  violate  contracts 83 

§  5.  Fallacy  that  we  can  predict  further  losses 85 

^  6.  Bimetallism  to  secure  stability  in  standard 86 

Chapter  XII.     The  theory  of  interest. 

\i.  "Real"  and  "nominal"  interest,  inadequate  terms,  88 


339]  Contents. 


vn 


I  2.  An  absolute  standard  is  individualistic 90 

I  3.  Interest  varies  with  length  of  contract 91 

§  4.  Multiple  theory  of  interest 91 


Appe;ndix.     StatisticaIv  Data. 

§  I.  Table  of  interest  rates  each  year  in  seven  countries  .    .  93 

I  2.  References  to  other  statistics  of  the  rate  of  interest  .    .  96 

I  3.  Index  numbers  of  prices  and  wages 98 


STATISTICAI.  TABLES. 

Rates  of  interest  realized  on  United  States  "coin"  and  "  cur- 
rency "  bonds  from  dates  mentioned  to  maturity 39 

Rates  of  interest  realized  on  United  States  "coin"  and  "cur- 
rency "  bonds  from  dates  mentioned  to  January   i,   1879, 

(date  of  Resumption) 42 

Rates  of  interest  realized  on  India  gold  and  silver  bonds  from 

dates  named  to  maturity  or  in  perpetuity 47 

Rates  of  interest  realized  on  India  gold  and  silver  bonds  for 

periods  specified 5^ 

Market  rates  of  interest  in  seven  countries,  in  relation  to  high 

and  low  prices ...  55 

London  rates  of  interest  in  relation  to  rising  and  falling  prices,         59 
Berlin  rates  of  interest  in  relation  to  rising  and  falling  prices  .  61 

Paris  rates  of  interest  in  relation  to  rising  and  falling  prices  .  61 

New  York  rates  of  interest  in  relation  to  rising  and  falling  prices 

and  wages "^ 

Average  bank  rates  in  gold  and  silver  standard  countries  before 

and  after  the  breakdown  of  bimetallism 64 

Rates  of  interest  in  relation  to  rising  and  falling  prices  in  Cal- 
cutta, Tokyo  and  Shanghai 65 

Number  of  cases  in  seven  countries  favorable  and  unfavorable 
to  the  theory  that  rising  and  falling  prices  are  associated 

respectively  with  high  and  low  interest 66 

London  market  rates  of  interest  in  relation  to  rising  and  falling 

prices,  wages  and  incomes  for  long  periods 7° 

New  York  rates  of  interest  in  relation  to  rising  and  falling 

prices  and  wages  for  long  periods 74 

Yearly  average  rates  of  interest  on  "money"  in  seven  coun- 
tries    94 

Index  numbers  for  seven  countries 99 


PREFACE. 


The  connection  between  monetary  appreciation  and    the 
rate  of  interest  has  received  very  scant  attention  from  econ- 
omists.    The  writer  has  been  led  to  beUeve  that  this  neglect 
has  somewhat  retarded  the  progress  of  economic  science  and 
the  successful  interpretation  of  economic  history — in  particu- 
lar the  monetary  history  of  the  last  twenty  years.     The  views 
here  put  forward  were  first  stated  in  brief  before  the  Ameri- 
can Economic  Association  at  Indianapolis,  December,  1895. 
They  differ  radically  from  those  expressed  by  Mr.  Giffen  and 
many  other  eminent  economists.     For  this  reason  it  has  been 
necessary  to  make  a  statistical  examination  of  all  available  facts 
bearing  on  the  subject.     Such  a  study  could  not  be  properly 
conducted  without  a  definite  economic  theory  as  a  starting 
point.     The  idea  on  which  this  theory  is  founded  appears  to 
have  occurred  independently  to  several  writers,  of  whom  Mr. 
Jacob  de  Haas,  Jr.,  of  Amsterdam,  seems  most  fully  to  have 
realized  its  importance.     To  develop  the  theory  in  a  quanti- 
tative form,  some  simple  mathematics  have  been  employed. 
With    numerical    illustrations    at    each    step,    it    is   hoped 
that  those  to  whom  mathematics  are  distasteful  will  find  few, 
if   any,  impediments   to   easy  reading.     The  mathematical 
reader,  on  the  other  hand,  may  feel  that  the  discussions  are 
too  much  encumbered  by  numerical  illustration  and  detail ; 
but  these  presentations  are  usually  in  such  a  form  that  they 
can  easily  be  passed  over  by  those  who  find  them  superfluous. 
The  gist  of  the  theory  is  contained  in  Chapter  II,  but  its 
statement  would  not  be  complete,  nor  the  apparent  objections 
to  it  fully  answered,  without  the  discussions  of  Chapters 
III-VI. 


X  Preface.  [342 

The  writer  is  greatly  indebted  to  the  many  persons  whose 
names  are  mentioned  in  the  text,  who  have  supplied  him 
with  important  facts  and  references  ;  also  to  Professor  Sum- 
ner for  the  privilege  of  consulting  his  collection  of  works  on 
banking  ;  to  Professor  Hadley,  for  valuable  suggestions  and 
criticisms ;  to  Mr.  Horace  White  for  pointing  out  the  im- 
portant pamphlet  of  the  eighteenth  century  mentioned  in 
Chapter  I ;  and  to  Mr.  Sakata  for  translating  several  statis- 
tical tables  from  Japanese. 

New  Haven,  August,  1896. 


PART  I.    THEORY. 
CHAPTER  I. 

INTRODUCTION. 

§1. 

The  chief  issues  in  the  bimetallic  controversy  center 
about  the  question  of  justice  between  debtor  and  creditor. 
The  bimetallic  propaganda  succeeds  just  so  far  as  it 
spreads  a  belief  that  an  injustice  has  been  done  by  the 
adoption  of  the  gold  standard,  which  the  re-adoption  of 
bimetallism  would  correct. 

The  question  therefore  arises,  does  the  appreciation  of 
gold  necessarily  aggravate  debts?  Are  contracting 
parties  powerless  to  forestall  the  gains  or  losses  of  an 
upward  or  downward  moving  currency  ?  It  is  clear  that 
if  the  unit  of  length  were  changed  and  its  change  were 
foreknown,  contracts  would  be  modified  accordingly. 
Suppose  a  yard  were  defined  (as  once  it  probably  was)  to 
be  the  length  of  the  king's  girdle,  and  suppose  the  king 
to  be  a  child.  Everybody  would  then  know  that  the 
"yard"  would  increase  with  age  and  a  merchant  who 
should  agree  to  deliver  i,ooo  "  yards  "  ten  years  hence, 
would  make  his  terms  correspond  to  his  expectations. 
To  alter  the  mode  of  measurement  does  not  alter  the 
actual  quantities  involved  but  merely  the  numbers  by 
which  they  are  represented. 

§2. 

Hitherto  monometallists  have  usually  replied  to  the 
argument  "gold  has  appreciated,  therefore  the  debtor 


2  American  Economic  Association.  [344 

has  been  robbed  "  by  challenging,  not  the  inference,  but 
the  premise.  Thus  the  discussion  has  been  shunted  off 
from  economic  theory  and  turned  into  a  controversy 
over  the  fact  of  "appreciation."  This  controversy  has 
been,  to  a  large  extent,  a  mere  war  of  words,  because,  by 
"  appreciation  "  the  monometallists  mean  one  thing  and 
the  bimetallists,  another.  No  one  has  ^-et  provided  a 
meaning  for  that  much  abused  word  acceptable  to  both 
parties.  The  bimetallists  prove  the  appreciation  of  gold 
by  the  fall  in  prices.  The  monometallists  reply  that 
wages  have  risen,  and  hold  that  the  fall  in  prices  is  due 
to  progress  in  the  arts.  Some  bimetallists,  e.  g.^  Leonard 
Courtney,^  accept  the  distinction  between  a  fall  in  prices 
through  causes  connected  with  gold  and  a  fall  through 
causes  connected  with  commodities,  but  most  of  them 
assert  that  a  "  fall  of  prices  "  and  "  appreciation  of  gold  " 
are  synonymous  expressions,  and  that,  if  progress  cheap- 
ens other  commodities,  it  ought  justly  to  cheapen  gold 
also.  Generally  speaking,  bimetallists  set  up  the  "  com- 
modity standard "  and  monometallists,  the  "  labor 
standard." 

Others  attempt  to  find  the  "just"  standard  in  "mar- 
ginal utility,"  "  total  utility,"  and  so  forth.  On  all  sides 
it  is  tacitly  assumed  that  a  "just"  standard  must  in 
some  sense  be  an  "  invariable "  standard ;  that  is,  a 
standard  such  that  the  principal  of  the  debt  when  due 
should  be  equivalent  in  some  way  to  the  original  loan. 
"  All  writers  on  the  subject  of  money  have  agreed  that 
uniformity  in  the  value  of  the  circulating  medium  is  an 
object  greatly  to  be  desired — a  currency  to  be  perfect, 
should  be  absolutely  invariable  in  value." "     Proposals 

1  Report  of  the  Indian  Currency  Committee,  1S93,  p.  39;  also, 
Nineteenth  Century,  April,  1893. 

^  Ricardo,  "Proposals  for  an  Economic  and  Secure  Curreuc}'," 
Sees.  I,  II. 


345]  Appreciation  and  Interest.  3 

to  define  and  secure  such  invariability  have  been  made 
by  many  writers.  Within  the  last  few  years,  the  prob- 
lem has  become  a  favorite  one  and  scarcely  an  issue  of 
the  economic  journals  appears  without  discussions  on 
"  The  ultimate  standard  of  value,"  "  The  just  standard 
of  deferred  payments,"  "  Has  gold  appreciated  ?  "  "  The 
measurement  of  the  value  of  money,"  and  kindred  sub- 
jects.^ 

§3. 
It  is  not  prosposed  to  deny  that  the  terms  appreciation 
and  depreciation  may  have  an  "  absolute  "  as  distinct 
from  a  "  relative  "  meaning.^  But  such  definitions  and 
distinctions  can  throw  no  light  whatever  on  the  question 
of  justice  in  contracts.  We  shall  see  that  a  standard  to 
be  perfect  need  not  be  invariable.  What  is  required  is 
simply  that  it  shall  be  dependable^  so  that  contracting 
parties  may  be  able  to  forecast  all  required  elements  of 
their  economic  future  in  terms  of  that  standard  as  accur- 
ately as  in  terms  of  any  other.  If  a  standard  is  thus  de- 
pendable, the  terms  of  the  contract  will  be  as  "just"  as 
they  could  possibly  be  under  any  system. 

§4. 

At  a  later  stage  the  general  question  of  "  justice  "  will 
be  discussed.  Here  the  effort  will  be  to  show  that  losses 
due  to  "  appreciation,"  however  defined,  will  tend  to  be 
forestalled.  For  this,  it  is  not  necessary  to  scale  the 
principal  of  a  debt.  The  principal  is  not  the  only  or 
even  the  chief  element  in  a  loan  contract.  The  other 
element  is  the  rate  of  interest.     It  is  an  astonishing  fact 

^See,  e.  g.,  the  connected  discussions  in  the  Annals  of  the  Ameri- 
can Academy  of  Political  and  Social  Science,  1892-95,  and  the  fournal 
of  Political  Economy,  1893-95,  by  Ross,  Merriam,  Fetter,  Commons, 
Newcomb,  Cummings,  Orton  and  Taylor. 

*  See  Chapter  XII. 


4  A7nerica7i  Economic  As,sociation.  [346 

that  tlie  connection  between  the  rate  of  interest  and  ap- 
preciation has  been  ahnost  completely  overlooked,  both 
in  economic  theory  and  in  its  bearing  upon  the  bime- 
tallic controversy. 

Of  the  few  writers  who  have  conceived  this  connection, 
apparentl}^  the  earliest  was  the  anonymous  author  of  the 
remarkable  pamphlet  entitled :  "  A  Discourse  Concerning 
the  Currencies  of  the  British  Plantations  in  America." 
Boston,  1740  (Reprinted  in  the  "  Overstone  Tracts," 
1857).     He  writes  : 

The  ArgU7nents  current  atnongst  the  Populace  in  favour  of  Paper 
Money,  are, 

I.  lu  most  of  the  Paper  Money  Colonies  one  of  the  principal  Rea- 
sons alledged  for  their  first  Emissions  ;  was,  to  prevent  Usurers  impos- 
ing high  Interest  upon  Borrowers,  from  the  Scarcity  of  Silver  Money. 
It  is  true,  that  in  all  Countries  the  increased  Quantity  of  Silver,  falls 
the  Interest  or  Use  of  Money  ;  but  large  Emissions  of  Paper  Money 
does  naturally  rise  the  Interest  to  make  good  the  sinking  Principal  :  for 
Instance,  in  the  Autumn,  A.  1737,  Silver  was  at  26  s.  to  27  s.  per  Ounce, 
but  by  a  large  Rhode  Island  Emission,  it  became  in  Autumn  1739,  29  s. 
per  Oz.  this  is  7  per  Cent.  Loss  of  Principal,  therefore  the  Lender,  to 
save  his  Principal  from  sinking,  requires  13  per  Cent,  natural  Interest 
(our  legal  Interest  being  6  per  Cent.)  for  that  Year.  In  Autumn  A. 
1733,  Silver  was  22  s.  per  Oz.  by  large  Emissions  it  became  27  s.  in 
the  Autumn,  A.  1734  ;  is  22  per  Cent,  loss  of  Principal  ;  and  the 
Lender  to  save  his  Principal  ;  requires  28  per  Cent,  natural  Interest 
for  that  Year.  Thus  the  larger  the  Emissions,  7iatural  Interest  be- 
comes the  higher ;  therefore  the  Advocates  for  Paper  Money  (who  are 
generally  indigent  Men,  and  Borrowers)  ought  not  to  complain,  when 
they  hire  Money  at  a  dear  nominal  Rate. 

If  Bills  were  to  depreciate  after  a  certain  Rate,  Justice  might  be 
done  to  both  contracting  Parties,  by  imposing  the  Loss  which  the 
Principal  may  sustain  in  any  certain  Space  of  Time  (the  Period  of 
Payment,  upon  the  Interest  of  a  Bond  or  Price  of  Goods  :  biit  as  De- 
preciations are  uncertain,  great  Confusions  in  Dealings  happen. 

John  Stuart  Mill    expresses  the   same    view,^  as    do 

^  "Principles  of  Political  Economy,"  Book  3,  Chapter  23,  \  4.  [A 
single  paragraph.] 


347]  Appreciation  and  hiterest.  5 

also  Jacob  de  Haas^  and  Professor  John  B.  Clark.^  A 
principle  which  apparently  has  been  independently  dis- 
covered by  each  of  these  economists  and  quite  possibly  by 
others,  is  likely  to  be  of  some  importance.  It  is  the  ob- 
ject of  the  present  essay  to  develop  the  theory  in  a  quan- 
titative form,  to  bring  it  to  a  statistical  test,  and  to  apply 
it  to  current  problems,  and  to  the  theory  of  interest. 

^  "  AThird  Element  in  the  Rate  of  Interest."  Journal  of  the  Royal 
Statistical  Society,  March,  1889.  [A  more  extended  discussion,  with 
statistics.] 

2  "  The  Gold  Standard  in  the  Light  of  Recent  Theory."  Political 
Science  Quarterly,  September,  1895.  [Applied  to  the  current  bime- 
tallic controvers}'.] 


CHAPTER  11. 

ONE  YEAR  contracts/ 

§1. 

We  must  begin  by  noting  the  distinction  between  a 
foreseen  and  an  nnforeseen  change  in  the  value  of  money. 
Only  the  losses  or  gains  of  the  former  can  be  forestalled. 
A  sudden  and  unexpected  inflation,  as  in  the  United 
States  in  1862,  works  enormous  losses  to  creditors  while 
an  unforeseen  contraction  is  equally  harmful  to  debtors. 

How  far  foresight  in  such  matters  actually  exists  will 
be  discussed  in  Part  II.  At  present  we  wish  to  discover 
what  will  happen,  assumiJig  this  foresight  to  exist. 

If  a  debt  is  contracted  optionally  in  either  of  two 
standards  and  one  of  them  is  expected  to  change  with 
reference  to  the  other,  will  the  rate  of  interest  be  the 
same  in  both  ?  Most  certainly  not.  Only  a  few  months 
ago  the  Belmont-Morgan  syndicate  offered  the  United 
States  government  the  alternative  of  taking  some  65 
millions  at  3/^  in  gold  or  at  3^/^  in  "coin."  Every- 
one knew  that  this  additional  ^  ^  was  due  to  the  mere 
possibility  of  free  silver  coinage.  If  the  alternatives  had 
been  between  repayment  in  gold  and — not  possible  but 
actual — repayment  in  silver,  the  additional  interest 
would  certainly  have  been  much  more  than  3/^  f/c . 

§2. 

To  fix  our  ideas,  let  the  two  standards  be  gold  and 
wheat,  and,  while  today  a  bushel  of  wheat  is  worth  a 

'  More  properly  speaking,  in  place  of  "one  j^ear  "  should  be  put 
"  one  interest  interval." 


349]  Appreciation  and  Interest.  7 

dollar,  let  it  be  known  that  one  year  hence  it  will  be 
worth  bnt  96  cents.  One  hundred  dollars  (gold  standard) 
or  its  equivalent  one  hundred  bushels  (wheat  standard) 
are  borrowed  today  and  are  to  be  repaid  with  interest  in 
one  year.  If  the  rate  of  interest  in  the  gold  standard  is 
8  'fo ,  what  will  be  the  rate  in  wheat  ? 

We  note  that  the  repayment,  if  in  gold,  will  be,  not 
$100  but  $108,  and  our  problem  is  solved  by  finding 
what  will  be  the  equivalent  of  this  sum  in  wheat  at  the 
end  of  the  year.  This  is  easily  obtained  from  the  ex- 
pected price  of  wheat,  thus  :  ^ 

96  cents  gold  =«=  i         bushel    wheat. 

Hence      i  dollar     "     —  ^i-    bushels      "     i.  e.,  \.o\\\>Vi. 

loS  dollars    "    —  loS  X  1.04I  bushels      "     i.  e.,    112^  bu. 

Thus  the  repayment  of  1 1 2^  bushels  will  be  equivalent 

to  $108.     The  alternative  contracts  would  tl\erefore  be  : 

\ 

For  100  dollars  borrowed  today,  108  dollars  are  due  one  year  hence. 
For  100  bushels  "  "        112  J  bushels    "      "     " 

Hence  8  fo  interest  in  the  gold  standard  is  equivalent 
to  12^%  in  the  wheat  standard. 

Now  the  relative  change  in  the  two  standards  may  be 
spoken  of  either  as  an  appreciation  of  gold  relatively  to 
wheat  or  as  a  depreciation  of  wheat  relatively  to  gold. 
We  are  not  compelled  to  inquire  which  is  the  "abso- 
lute" change.  If  we  speak  in  terms  of  appreciation,  we 
say  $1  changes  in  value  from  i  bushel  of  wheat  to  1.04% 
bushels  and  hence  has  appreciated  4}i'/o  ]  while  we  may 
also  say,  wheat  has  depreciated  from  ^i  to  $.g6  or  4^. 
Our  results  can  be  stated  in  either  of  two  ways : 

I.  If  the  rate  of  interest  in  one  standard  is  8^,  then 
in  another,  which  depreciates  4  fo  relatively  to  the  first, 
it  will  be  12  }4fo  ;  that  is,  a  depreciation  of  4^  is  offset 
by  an  increase  of  interest  of  4}^  fo. 

1  The  symbol  "  =0=  "  is  used  for  "  are  equivalent  to." 


8  American  Economic  Association.  [350 

2.  If  the  rate  of  interest  in  one  standard  is  12)^  %,  in 
another,  which  appreciates  4  ^-^  /^  relatively  to  the  first, 
it  will  be  8 ;%  ;  that  is,  an  appreciation  of  4  )^  ^  is  offset 
by  a  decrease  of  interest  of  4j^  /^. 

§3. 

Leaving  this  numerical  case,  we  may  state  the  problem 
more  generally.  Suppose  gold  is  to  appreciate  relatively 
to  wheat  a  certain  known  amount  in  one  year.  What 
will  be  the  relation  between  the  rates  of  interest  in  the 
two  standards  ?  Let  wheat  fall  in  gold  price  (or  gold 
rise  in  wheat  price)  so  that  the  quantity  of  gold  which 
would  buy  one  bushel  of  wheat  at  the  beginning  of  the 
year  will  buy  1  -\-  a  bushels  at  the  end,  a  being  therefore 
the  rate  of  appreciation  of  gold  in  terms  of  wheat. 

Let  the  rate  of  interest  in  gold  be  z,  and  in  wheat  be 
y,  and  let  the  principal  of  the  loan  be  D  dollars  or  its 
equivalent  B  bushels. 

Our  alternative  contracts  are  then  : 

For  D  dollars  borrowed  D-\-D i  or  D  { i-\-i)  dollars  are  due  in  one  yr. 
For  ^bushels         "  i5  f  5/ or  ^  ( i+y)  bushels  "     "  "     " 

and  our  problem  is  to  find  the  relation  between  i  and/, 
which  will  make  the  Z>(i  +  2)  dollars  =g=  the  B (1  -]-j) 
bushels. 

At  first,  D  dollars  -  B  bu. 

At  the  end  of  the  year  Z>  "      ^  B  {\+a) 

Hence      "  "  "       Z>(i+?)         "      =0=  i?  ( i-f  rt)  (1  +  /)      " 

Since  Z)(i  +  i)  is  the  number  of  dollars  necessary  to 
liquidate  the  debt,  its  equivalent  B {1  +  a)  (i  +  2)  is  the 
number  of  bushels  necessary  to  liquidate  it.  But  we 
have   already   designated    this   number   of    bushels  by 

Our  result,  therefore,  is  : 


35 1]  Appreciation  and  Interest.  9 

Dollars.  Bushels.  Buishels. 

At  the  end  of  i  yearZ?(r  +  /)  ^  B  {\  -^j)  =  B  {\  -\-  a)  {\  ^  i)       (i) 

which,  after  B  is  canceled,  discloses  the  formula  : 

i+y=(i+«)  (i+o  (2) 

or  j=--^^-a-\-ia  (3) 

or  in  words  :  The  rate  of  interest  in  the  (^relatively)  de- 
preciating standard  is  equal  to  the  sum  of  three  terms^ 
vis.^  the  rate  of  interest  in  the  appreciatittg  standard., 
the  rate  of  appreciation  itself  and  the  prodicct  of  these 
two  elemeiits. 

Thus,  to  offset  appreciation,  the  rate  of  interest  must 
be  lowered  by  slightly  more  than  the  rate  of  apprecia- 
tion/ 

We  may  introduce  depreciation  in  a  similar  manner. 
Instead  of  saying,  gold  appreciates  at  the  rate  «,  rela- 
tively to  wheat,  we  may  say,  wheat  depreciates  at  the 
rate  (f,  relatively  to  gold.^  This  means  that  wheat  has 
sunk  in  terms  of  gold  in  the  ratio  i  to  i  —  ^,  and  rea- 
soning similar  to  the  foregoing  shows  that 

i4-^  =  (i-^)(i+y).  (4) 

Equations  (2)  and  (4)  may  be  conveniently  combined, 
thus  : 

i  +  «         I  i—d'  ^^' 

'Professor  Clark,  {Political  Science  Quarterly,  September,  1895), 
implies  that  i  %  appreciation  is  offset  by  less  than  i  %  reduction  of 
interest.  But  in  making  his  calculation  he  has  failed  to  "compound." 
The  numerical  illustrations  of  the  eighteenth  century  pamphleteer 
{supra)  are  also  erroneous.  E.g.,  instead  of  28  %,  should  be  29.32 
%.  Professor  Marshall,  ("  Principles  of  Economics,"  Vol.  T,  3rd  ed., 
p.  674),  gives  a  correct  example.  His  example  is  designed  to  show 
the  losses  from  a  fluctuating  currency  and  not  the  effort  to  offset  these 
losses.  He  appears,  however,  to  have  in  mind  this  effort  when  he 
postpones  to  the  next  volume  the  discussion  of  "  the  influences  which 
changes  in  the  purchasing  power  of  money  do  actually  exert  on  the 
terms  on  which  loans  are  arranged,"  (p.  673). 

■■^  The  relation  between  rfandais  (i+a)  (r— ^)  =  i,  which  is  evi- 
dent from  equation  (5)  or  can  be  easily  shown  independently. 


lo  Amej'icaji  Economic  Association.  [352 

Since       ' —  is  the  ratio  of  the  vahie  of  gold  at  the  end 

of  the  year  to  its  vahie  at  the  beginning  (all  in  terms  of 
wheat),  that  is,  the  ratio  of  divergence  of  the  two  stand- 
ards expressed  in  wheat,  while  is  the  same  ratio 

I  —  d 

of  divergence  expressed  in  gold,  and  since  i  +  i  is  the 
"  amount  "  of  $1  put  at  interest  for  one  year  while  i  +7 
is  the  "  amount "  of  one  bushel ;  we  may  state  equation 
(5)  as  follows  : 

The  ratio  of  divergence  betiveen  the  standards  equals 
the  ratio  between  their  "  ainoiints^ 

■  This  is,  perhaps,  the  simplest  mode  of  conceiving  the 
relation  and  stress  is  laid  upon  it  because  it  brings  into 
prominence  the  "  amount,"  or  ratio  of  future  payment  to 
present  loan,  a  magnitude  which  in  most  questions  of  in- 
terest plays  a  more  important  role  than  the  rate  of  in- 
terest itself/ 

Equation  (5)  gives  the  relation  between  i  and  /  in 
terms  of  a  or  d.  From  it,  follows  the  value  of/  in  terms 
either  of  i  and  a  or  of  i  and  d^  and  also  the  value  of  i  in 
terms  either  of  y'  and  a  or  of  y'  and  <^,  thus  : 

I  +  ^  I  1  —  a 

whence  j  =:i  -\-  a  -\-  i  a -^  (6) 

I  —  d 

or  i  =j  —  d  —j  d  ^~-^  ( 7 ) 

I  -r  a 

^  In  fact,  except  for  convenience  in  computation,  the  conception  of 
the  rate  of  interest  might  well  be  dispensed  with,  giving  place  to  the 
conception  of  a  year's  "amount"  or  "ratio  of  accumulation."  In 
his  "Positive  Theory  of  Capital,"  Professor  Bolim-Bawerk  expresses 
the  same  view.  (English  Translation,  p.  296).  We  should  then  speak, 
not  of  a  6  %  rate  of  interest,  but  of  1.06  as  the  "  ratio  of  accumula- 
tion." In  like  manner  "  rate  of  appreciation  "  would  give  place  to 
"  ratio  of  appreciation."  Denoting  the  ratio  of  accumulation,  i  -\-  j, 
by  r^  and  i  +  ^  by  r,  and  the  "  ratio  of  appreciation,"  i  -p  a,  by />,  our 

theorem  becomes  simply    -  =/>. 
r 


353]  Appreciation  and  Interest. 


II 


It  follows  that  j  exceeds  i  by  more  than  the  rate  of 
appreciation,  which  in  turn  is  more  than  the  rate  of  de- 
preciation, {i.  e.^j —  i^  ay>  d). 

§4- 

It  is  to  be  noted  that  we  have  been  regarding  money 
as  a  standard  of  value  and  not  as  a  medium  of  exchange. 
In  either  contract  the  actual  liquidation  need  not  be 
made  either  in  gold  or  wheat  but  in  some  other  medium, 
as  bank  notes.  The  speculator  who  sells  wheat  "  short," 
really  uses  wheat  as  a  standard  and  not  necessarily  as  a 
medium.  In  consideration  of  value  received  today 
(which,  though  reckoned  by  the  speculator  in  money, 
may  readily  be  thought  of  as  measured  in  wheat)  he 
promises  to  deliver,  at  a  later  date,  so  many  bushels  of 
wheat,  it  being  perhaps  understood  that  he  need  not  act- 
ually deliver  the  wheat  so  long  as  he  delivers  its  equiv- 
alent in  money.  This  operation,  as  actually  practiced, 
involves  great  uncertainties,  and  therefore  occurs  as  a 
gambling  transaction.  Moreover  the  wheat  is  not 
usually  paid  for  in  advance.  But  if  wheat  were  a  more 
reliable  standard,  selling  it  "  short  "  in  consideration  of 
present  advances  might  be  a  true  method  of  business 
borrowing,  and  would  then  exactly  exemplify  the  case 
we  have  supposed.  In  fact,  such  contracts  are  identical 
in  form  with  those  which  would  be  made  under  the 
oft-proposed  "  multiple  standard." 


CHAPTER  III. 

MORE  THAN  ONE  YEAR. 
§1. 

A  prominent  bimetallist  in  conversing  with  the  writer 
on  the  subject  of  interest  and  appreciation,  raised  the 
following  objection:  "Interest  and  principal  are  sepa- 
rate ;  the  one  is  paid  regularly  in  installments  ;  the  other 
remains  to  the  end  ;  hence  appreciation  must  affect  them 
in  totally  different  ways.  I  do  not  see  how  it  is  possible 
by  a  uniform  reduction  in  interest  applied  to  contracts 
of  different  periods  to  offset  the  appreciation  of  both 
interest  and  principal."  This  view,  as  we  shall  soon 
see,  is  quite  erroneous  and  arises  from  the  habit  of 
separating  in  thought  interest  and  principal. 


First  consider  the  case  in  which  no  interest  is  paid 
until  the  end  of  the  term  of  years.  Let  us  suppose, 
for  instance,  a  savings  bank  which  receives  $ioo,  gold 
standard,  and  repays  the  depositor  in  five  years  at  5  ^ 
compound  interest.  If  there  were  an  alternative 
standard,  say  wheat,  in  terms  of  which  gold  is  known  to 
appreciate  ^  constantly  by  i  ^  per  annum,  what  would 
be  the  rate  of  interest  in  this  standard  ?  We  shall  sup- 
pose for  convenience  that  at  first  the  price  of  wheat  is 
$1  per  bushel. 

^  Or  what  is  equivalent,  wheat  depreciates  ygx^  relatively  to  gold. 
As  it  will  be  understood  that  there  are  always  these  two  modes  of  ex- 
pressing the  relative  change  of  two  standards,  we  shall  hereafter 
adhere  to  "appreciation." 


355]  Appreciation  and  Interest.  13 

If  the  repayment  were  to  come  in  one  year,  we  know 

from  Chapter  I,  §  3,  that  the  rate  of  interest  in  wheat  is 

given  by  the  formula 

j^i-{-a-\-ta 
=  .05  +  .01  +.0005 
=  .060^ 

This  result  is  as  truly  the  answer  to  our  problem  for  a 
series  of  years  as  for  one  year.  The  proof  consists 
simply  in  separating  the  contract  into  several  contracts 
of  one  year  each.  Thus,  by  Chapter  II,  we  know  if  we 
deposit  today  1 100  or  its  equivalent,  100  bushels,  it  will 
amount  in  i  year  to  $105  at  5;^  or  its  equivalent,  106.05 
bushels,  at  6^^o.  We  may  now  regard  these  equiv- 
alent amounts  as  withdrawn  but  immediately  redeposited 
for  one  year.  Then,  with  the  same  rate  of  interest  in 
gold  and  the  same  rate  of  relative  appreciation,  we  shall 
obtain  the  same  rate  of  interest  in  wheat,  so  that  $105.00 
or  its  equivalent,  106.05  bushels,  will  amount  in  i  year 
to  I110.25  ^t  5^,  or  its  equivalent,  112.47  bushels  at 
6-^^.  In  this  way  each  successive  pair  of  "  amounts," 
including  the  last,  will  be  equivalent. 


The  principle  employed  in  §  2  is  to  resolve  the  contract 
into  a  series  of  one  year  contracts.  The  general  case  is 
precisely  similar.  For  the  first  year  we  have,  by 
formula  (i).  Chapter  II, 

Dollars  due.      Bushels  due.  Bushels  due. 

D{i  +  i)<^B{i+j)=B{i  +  a){i-\-i) 

In  the  second  year  the  same  formula  applies  except 
that  in  place  of  Z?,  the  principal  is  now  Z>  (i  +  2),  and 
in  place  of  B,  B  (i  +/)  or  ^  (i  +  a)  (i  +  i).  Making 
these  substitutions  in  the  formula,  we  obtain 


l>[\       iV  -^  /.\i    ,  ,/y       /*(i    I  aY  [i    !   i'Y 
A\\<\  similuK  in  tlu-  thli\l  year, 

aiul  sv»  vMi.     Kach  of  the  results  discloses  the  priuoiple 

1\\  §$  J  i\iv*.l  ^^>  we  began  for  simplicity  with  the  case 
in  which  the  debt  is  allowetl  to  accmuulate  to  the  end. 
The  most  general  ease,  however,  is  one  in  which  the  re- 
|x^yn\ents  are  in  installments. 

Suppose,  as  in  §  3,  that  the  interest  in  gold  is  5  '/c  and 
that  gold  is  known  to  appreciate  i  %  per  annum  rela- 
tively to  wheat.  A  fanner  mortgages  his  land  for  $i.ckx> 
oar  its  then  e<jnivaleut,  i>ooo  bushels  of  wheat,  and  agrees 
to  pay  annually  the  interest  and  such  parts  of  the  principal 
as  he  can  save,  tnaking  the  repayment  complete  in  7  years. 
Our  problem  is  to  find  that  rate  of  interest  in  wheat 
which  will  make  the  contracts  in  gold  and  wheat 
e<^uivaleut  iu  every  respect. 

The  solution  of  this  problem  is  precisely  the  same  as 
that  of  §  2,  viz.,  65^  %,  For.  at  the  end  of  one  year,  the 
farmer's  debt  amounts  to  $1050  or  its  then  equivalent, 
io6<X50  bushels,  Let  us  suppose  that  he  finds  himself 
aUeto  pay,  not  only  the  ^4nterest>"  $50,  but  also  $50  of 
the  ^'  principal,' *  that  is  $100  altogether.  The  equi\^ 
lent  of  this  iu  wheat  is  ici. 00  bu. 

Hence  he  cart  either 

pay  $ic>o,<x>        oa  $1,050,00,        leavnng  $95aoo 

or  101,00  bu,  Qu.  1,060^50  bu.,  leaving  959^ 50  bn. 
aod,  since  the  ^"amounts"  $1,050  and  1,060,50  bu,  are 
e^ilu\^ilent  and  the  deductions;  $ioo  and  ioi,oo  bu,  are 


557] 


Appreciation  and  Interest. 


15 


equivalent,  the  remainders  $950  and  959.50  bu.  must  also 
be  equivalent ;  and,  in  fact,  this  may  be  seen  directly 
since,  with  gold  appreciating  i  ^ ,  $950,  originally  worth 
950  bu.,  becomes  worth  i  ^  more,  or  959.50  bu. 

Thus  the  farmer's  remaining  debt  at  the  end  of  the 
first  year  is  the  same  whether  measured  in  wheat  or 
gold  and  since  the  same  reasoning  applies  to  the  second 
year,  third  year,  etc.,  the  equivalence  remains  to  the  end 
of  the  contract. 

It  is  worth  noting  here  that  the  $100  payment  in  gold 
will  be  regarded  as  consisting  of  half  interest  and  half 
principal,  whereas  the  equivalent  payment  in  wheat, 
101.00  bu.,  consists  of  60.50  bu.,  interest  and  40.50  bu., 
principal. 

The  liquidation  of  the  contract  during  the  7  years 
may  be  supposed  to  take  place  in  either  of  the  following 
equivalent  ways  : 

GOLD  STANDARD. 


I 
Interest.     1    Amount. 

Paj-ment. 

Prixicipal. 

At  beginning 

|i,ooo.oo 
950.00 
900.00 
800.00 
690. 00 

550.00 

300.00 
0.00 

In  I  year 

In  2  years 

':\i  ■::■:■:■. 

"6      "      

"7      "      

I50.00 
47-50 
45.00 
40.00 
34-50 
27.50 
15.00 

^1,050.00 
997-50 
945.00 
840.00 
724-50 
577-50 
315-00 

|ioo.oo 
97-50 
145.00 
150.00 
174-50 
277-50 
315-00 

WHEAT  STANDARD. 


Interest. 

Amount. 

Paj-ment. 

Printripal. 

At  beginning 

1,000.00  bu. 

In  I  year 

In  2  years 

"3      "       

"4      "       

'•5      "      

"6      "      

"7      "      

60.50 
58.05 
55  54 
49-87 
43-44 
34-97 
19.27 

1,060.50 
1,017-55 
973-63 
874- 1 1 
761.46 
61303 
337-73 

101.00 
99.46 

149-39 
156.09 
183.40 
294-57 
337-73 

959-50    " 
91S.09    " 
824.24    " 
718.02     " 
57S.06    " 
318-46    " 
0.00    " 

In  these  two  tables  ever}-  entrs"  in  one  is  equivalent  to 


i6  American  Economic  Association.  [358 

the  corresponding  entry  in  the  other  except  those  in  the 
interest  columns. 

We  thus  see  that  the  farmer  who  contracts  a  mortgage 
in  gold  is,  if  the  interest  is  properly  adjusted^  no  worse 
and  no  better  off  than  if  his  contract  were  in  a  "  wheat  " 
standard  or  a  "  multiple  "  standard. 

§5- 
The  principle  involved  in  §  4  is  that  equivalent  pay- 
ments subtracted  from  equivalent  "  amounts  "  will  leave 
equivalent  remainders.  The  payment  in  any  year  forms 
the  same  fractional  part  of  the  "  amount  "  in  the  two 
standards.  We  may  designate  this  fraction  at  the  end 
of  the  first  year  by  y^  the  second  year  by  _/',  etc.,  and 
we  have  the  following  results  : 

END   OF  FIRST   YFAR. 
Dollars.  Bushels.  Bushels. 

Amount.  i?(i+/)*  ^(i+y)=  ^  (1+^)  ( i-|./) 

Paym't  f  D  {\^i)  -^  fB{i-^j)=  f  B  {\^a)  (i+z) 

R'md'r  .  (I-/)  Dii^i)  <^  (i-/)  B{i^j  )  =  (i-/)  B{x^a)  (1+/) 
In  like  manner  the  unpaid  remainder  at  the  end  of  the 
second  year  can  be  shown  to  be 

Dollars.  Bushels.  Bushels. 

(I-/')  (I-/)  D  (1+0=  *    (I-/')  (I-/)  B  (i+y)2=    (I-/')  (I-/)  B  (i+ar-  (1+02 

and  so  on  for  any  number  of  years.     Each  result  again 
yields  the  formula  (i  +/)  =  (!  +  «)  (i  +  z). 

This  includes,  of  course,  the  case  of  §  i,  in  which  no 
partial  payments  are  made,y^y"',  etc.,  being  then  zero. 

§6. 

One  special  case  may  seem  to  require  separate  consid- 
eration. Suppose  the  interest  alone  is  annually  paid  and 
the  principal  redeemed  at  the  end,  as  in  the  case  of  a 
bond  not  subject  to  a  sinking  fund.  What  correspond- 
ence between  the  two  standards  is  then  possible  ?  The 
following  tables  answer  this  question,  the  first,  for  the 


359] 


Appreciation  and  Interest. 


17 


case  where  the  wheat  interest,   the  second,  where  the 
gold  interest  is  annually  paid. 


TABLE  I. 


TABI,E  II. 


Interest. 

Amount. 

Payment. 

Principal. 

At  beginning  (Bushels^ 

1,000.00 

In     I  year .    .    .    ' 

• 

60.50 

1,060.50 

60.50 

1,000.00 

"     2  years.  . 

"     3      " 

«'     4      '« 
"     5      " 

«     6      << 

"     7      " 
"     8      " 
"     9      " 

' 

"  10      " 

1,060.50 

0.00 

At  bep^inning  (Doll^i's^ 

1,000.00 

In    I  year .    .    .     ' 

' 

50.00 

1,050.00 

59-90 

990. 10 

' '     2  years  .  . 

49-50 

1,039.60 

59-31 

980.29 

"     3      " 

. 

49.01 

1,029.30 

58.72 

970.58 

"     4      '• 

48.53 

1,019.11 

58.14 

960.97 

"     5      " 

48.05 

1,009.02 

57.56 

951.46 

"     6      " 

. 

47-57 

999.03 

56.99 

942.04 

"     7      " 

47.15 

989.19 

56.43 

932.76 

"     8      " 

46.63 

979-39 

55.87 

923.52 

<<     g      .< 

46.17 

969.69 

55.32 

914.37 

"  10      " 

• 

45-71 

960.08 

960.08 

0.00 

At  beginning  (Busi 
In    I  year .    .    .    ' 

lels) 

1,000.00 

60.50 

1,060.50 

50.50 

1,010.00 

"     2  years. 

'             61.10 

1,071.10 

51.00 

1,020.10 

"3      "     • 

'             61.72 

1,081.82 

51.52 

1,030.30 

"4      "    . 

62.32 

1,092.62 

52.03 

1,040.59 

"5      "    • 

'             62.96 

1,103.55 

52.55 

1,051.00 

"6      "     . 

63.59 

1,114-59 

53-08 

1,061.51 

"7      "     . 

'             64.22 

1,125.73 

53-61 

1,072.12 

"8      "     . 

64.86 

1,136.98 

54.14 

1,082.84 

"9      "     . 

65.51 

1,148.35 

54.68 

1,093.67 

"  10      "     . 

66.17 

1,159.84 

1,159.84 

0.00 

At  beginning  (Del 
In    I  year .    .    .    ' 

lars)   

1,000.00 

'              50.00 

1,050.00 

50.00 

1,000.00 

"     2  years. 
"3      "     • 
"4      "     . 
"5      "    • 
"6      "    . 

< 

"7      "    . 
"8      "    . 

"9      "    . 

"  10      "    . 

(                 (( 

1,050.00 

0.00 

1 8  America7i  Economic  Association.  [360 

From  Table  I,  it  will  be  seen  that  the  case  in  the 
wheat  standard,  in  which  only  the  interest  is  annnally 
paid  and  the  principal  redeemed  in  ten  years  is  equiva- 
lent, step  for  step,  in  the  gold  standard  to  a  series  of 
small  partial  payments.  Thus,  instead  of  paying  merely 
the  annual  interest  of  I50,  the  sum  paid  the  first  year  is 
$59.90  reducing  the  principal  by  $9.90.  At  the  end 
there  is  due  I914.37  of  principal  and  $45.71  of  interest, 
making  $960.08  in  all,  which  at  that  date  is,  of  course, 
precisely  equivalent  to  the  1,060.50  bushels,  the  final 
payment  in  wheat. 

On  the  other  hand,  the  case  in  which  the  gold  interest 
payments  are  kept  up,  corresponds  to  a  series  of  wheat 
payments  less  than  the  annual  interest,  so  that  the  un- 
paid interest  accumulated  to  the  end  makes  the  sum  then 
due,  1,159.84  bu.,  of  which  1,093.67  bu.  are  principal. 

It  is  thus  clear  that  the  case  in  which  in  one  standard 
the  interest  is  paid  annually  and  the  principal  at  the 
end,  can  be  exactly  matched  in  the  other  standard  either 
by  minute  partial  payments  or  minute  arrears  of  interest. 
Without  such  partial  payments  or  arrears  in  one  of  the 
standards,  the  two  would  not  be  equivalent  step  for  step. 
We  shall  see,  however,  that  they  would  still  be  equiva- 
lent as  a  whole. 


CHAPTER  IV. 

"  PRESENT  VAI^UE." 


In  practice,  of  course  no  such  minute  partial  payments 
of  principal  or  minute  remissions  of  interest  would  be 
made.  Any  advantages  to  be  derived  from  such  calcula- 
tions of  trifles  would  not  be  worth  the  trouble.  But 
even  if  we  destroy  the  precise  step-for-step  equivalence 
between  the  wheat  and  gold  tables,  we  do  not  destroy 
their  equivalence  as  a  whole.  The  '•^present  values  " 
remain  exactly  equal. 

The  ordinary  definition  of  the  "  present  value  "  of  a 
given  sum  due  at  a  future  date  is  "  thai  sum  which  put 
at  interest  today  will  '  amount '  to  the  given  sum  at 
that  future  date."  "  Present  value  "  and  "  amount  "  are 
thus  correlative  terms.  In  fact  we  may  extend  the  pre- 
ceding definition  to  include  the  present  value  of  past 
sums  as  the  accumulated  "  amount "  today  of  the  past 
sum  put  at  interest  then. 

The  literal  meaning  of  "  present  value  "  implies  that 
it  is  the  actual  market  price  today  of  a  future  sum  due. 
This  is,  in  fact,  the  case.  We  need  not  stop  to  prove  it 
in  theory,  for  we  are  all  familiar  with  it  in  practice. 
Elaborate  tables  are  constructed  on  this  principle  for  the 
practical  use  of  insurance  companies  in  calculating  their 
premiums,  and  for  brokers  in  determining  the  compara- 
tive merits  of  various  bond  investments.  What  we  are 
here  concerned  with  is  applying  the  principle  to  our 
problem. 


20  A7ficrican  Ecoyiomic  Association.  [362 

§2. 

If  a  debt  of  $1,000  is  contracted  today,  interest  being 
5^,  the  "present  value"  of  all  payments,  principal  and 
interest,  by  which  that  debt  is  to  be  liquidated  is  exactly 
$1,000.^  Again,  the  debt's  present  value,  reckoned  at  a 
later  date  than  the  time  of  contract,  is  the  "  amount "  of 
$1,000  at  interest  from  the  time  of  contract  to  that  date, 
and  this  is  true,  whether  or  not  any  of  the  debt  has  al- 
ready been  paid.  Thus  if  the  present  values  at  the  date 
of  contract  are  computed  for  the  gold  and  the  wheat 
debts  of  the  last  chapter,  they  will  be  $1,000  and  1,000 
bushels,  which  are  then  equivalent.  If  the  present  val- 
ues one  year  later  are  taken  they  are  $1,050  and  1060.50 
bushels  which  at  that  date  are  also  equivalent,  gold  hav- 
ing appreciated  i  fo . 

From  these  familiar  principles,  it  follows  that  the 
present  values  of  the  two  debts,  reckoned  at  any  date 
whatever,  are  identical  whether  the  individual  payments 
correspond  or  not.  Thus,  to  take  the  case  first  referred 
to,  suppose  the  wheat  debt  to  be  discharged  as  in  Table  I 
and  the  gold  debt,  as  in  Table  II.  The  present  value,  at 
the  date  of  contract,  of  the  interest  and  principal,  sepa- 
rately computed,  will  be  •? 

Dollars.        Bushels. 

Present  value  of  all  interest  payments  .    .    .    ,  386.09  <    444.24 

"         "  principal  due  in  10  years  .    .  613.91  >    555.76 

"         "  total 1000.00  "^  1000.00 

If  the  present  values  (including  "  amounts  "  of  past 

'  This  and  the  other  general  theorems  on  present  value  are  not  proved 
here  because  their  proof  is  accessible  in  most  treatises  on  interest,  an- 
nuities, insurance,  etc.  See,  e.g.,  the  "Encyclopaedia  Britannica," 
"  Annuities." 

'^  The  symbol  <  is  here  used  for  "is  less  than  the  equivalent  of " 
and  >  for  "is  more  than  the  equivalent  of." 


363]  Appreciatio7i  and  Interest.  21 

interest)  were  computed  5  years  after  the  date  of  the 
contract,  the  items  would  be  : 

Dollars.       Bushels. 

Interest 492-75  <    595-88 

Principal 783-53  >    745-5° 

Total 1276.28-1341.38 

We  thus  see  that  it  would  be  just  as  much  a  hardship 
to  pay  the  high  interest  in  wheat  as  to  pay  the  more 
onerous  principal  in  gold, 

§3- 

The  case  of  a  perpetual  annuity  may  be  given  special 
consideration.  As  is  well  known,  the  present  value  of  a 
perpetual  annuity  is  its  "  capitalized  "  value.  Thus,  if 
the  rate  of  interest  is  taken  at  5  ^ ,  the  present  value  of 
a  perpetual  annuity  of  $50  per  annum  is  $1,000.  Ap- 
plying the  same  principle  to  the  wheat  annuity  of  60.50 
bushels  and  extending  the  previous  reasoning,  we  find 
that  the  two  annuities  are  equivalent. 

At  first  sight  this  seems  impossible  since  6-^  ^  is  a 
higher  rate  of  interest  than  5^.  This  is  true  in  the 
numerical  sense,  and  it  is  also  true  that  the  early  pay- 
ments of  60.50  bushels  are  actually  more  valuable  than 
$50.  But  after  a  certain  time  (in  this  case  19  years)  the 
reverse  is  true.  The  19th  payment  of  $50  in  gold  is 
worth  60.40  bushels  while  the  20th  is  worth  61.01  bush- 
els. That  is,  the  recipient  of  the  wheat  annuity  has  at 
first  a  slight  advantage  over  the  recipient  of  the  gold 
annuity  which  ceases  and  becomes  a  slight  disadvantage 
after  19  years. 

§4. 

To  derive  the  formula  for  the  time  at  which  the  rela- 
tive values  of  the  two  annuities  become  reversed,  let  the 
rate  of  interest  in  gold  be  z,  in  wheat,/;  let  the  two  an- 


22  American  Economic  Associatio7i.  [364 

nuities  be  D  i  and  B  j^  their  capitalized  values  being  D 
and  B  [D  =c=  ^  at  the  beginning)  and  let  x  be  the  num- 
ber of  years  in  which  BJ  is  as  valuable  as  or  more  val- 
uable than  D  i.     Then 

Bushels.  Dollars. 

At  end  of  x  years,      -      -     -      B  j     >      Di 
At  end  of  .r  +  i  years,       -        B j     <      Di 

and  since  we  know  that  in  x  years,  D  ^  B  {\  ^-  a)'  and 
hence  Di  o-  Bt(i  ^  a)']  and  likewise  in  .r  +  i  years, 
Di  =0=  B  i{\  +  cl)""^^ ^  we  see  that  the  previous  inequal- 
ities become : 

Bushels.  Bu.shels. 

At  end  of  x  years,     -     Bj     >     Bi(i  ^  aY 
At  end  of  ;i;  +  i  years,  Bj      <     Bi{i  -\-  <^)-^+ ' 

which  may  be  combined  in  the  formula : 

i  (i  +aK^y  <i  (i  +«)^+  I 

^<log/^log^      ^_^^_  (8) 

—  log(i+a) 

That  is,  X  is  the  integral  part  of  the  number 

log  J  —  log  t 

log  (I  +«)■ 

Thus,  if  2^.05,  a  =  .01,  and  hence  also/ =.0605, 

then 

logy  —  log  z_  2.7818  —  2.6990 .0828 

log  ( I  +  a)  .0043  "~  .0043  ~ 

Hence  x  =  ig. 


CHAPTER  V. 

VARYING   RATES   OF   INTEREST   AND   APPRECIATION. 

§1. 

Hitherto  we  have  assumed  that  the  appreciation  pro- 
ceeded (during  the  period  of  the  contract)  at  a  constant 
percentage  rate  per  annum,  and  that  the  rate  of  interest 
(in  one  standard,  and  consequently  in  the  other)  remained 
constant  also.  The  more  general  case  is  one  in  which 
these  elements  are  changing. 

Beginning  with  a  numerical  case,  let  us  suppose  that 
the  United  States  government  is  offered  an  alternative 
loan,  not  in  gold  or  "  coin,"  but  in  gold  or  silver.  Let 
it  be  known  that  lOO  gold  dollars  will  remain  at  par  the 
first  year,  but  in  two  years  will  be  worth  150  silver  dol- 
lars, that  is,  gold  will  "  appreciate,"  in  the  second  year, 
50  ^  relatively  to  silver ;  also  that  in  the  third  and 
fourth  years  it  will  appreciate  10  fo  and  5^  respectively. 
We  shall  suppose  that  the  rate  of  interest,  if  the  con- 
tract be  in  gold,  is  3  ^  for  each  year  of  the  contract. 

Our  problem  is  to  discover  what  will  be  the  interest 
in  silver.  It  is  perhaps  already  evident  that  it  will  be  a 
different  rate  for  each  year.  If  the  contract  were  made 
for  one  year  only,  the  rate  of  interest  in  silver  would 
also  be  3  ^ ,  since  silver  remains  so  far  at  par  with  gold. 
If  the  contract  (or  any  unpaid  part  of  it)  were  then  re- 
newed for  a  second  year,  the  rate  of  interest  would  be, 

by  formula  (3) : 

j  =  z  -\-  a-\-  ai 
=  .03 +  .50  + -015 
=  .545 

=  54i% 


24  American  Economic  Association.  [366 

In  like  manner,  we  may  deduce  the  rate  of  interest  in 
each  year,  with  the  following  results  : 

Gold  Silver  Appre- 

Standard.  Standard.  ciation. 

istyear   ......  3%  3     %  0% 

2d  year 3  54^  50 

3d  year 3  13^  10 

4ttiyear 3  SyVj  5 

Etc. 


The  question  arises,  can  a  single  "  average  "  rate  of 
interest  be  substituted  for  the  above  irregular  series  ? 

We  answer  that  such  an  average  is  not  possible  if  the 
debtor  has  the  option  of  arbitrary  partial  payments. 
If,  for  instance,  the  average  were  20^,  and  the  govern- 
ment could  pay  ofi  at  any  time,  it  would  evidently  be 
tempted  to  refund  the  debt  at  the  end  of  the  second 
year,  to  which  the  lending  syndicate  would  not  agree. 
If,  however,  the  conditions  as  to  repayment  are  stipulated 
for  in  advance,  an  average  can  easily  be  computed  on  the 
principle  of  present  values. 

Suppose  the  government  agrees  to  extinguish  the 
debt  in  four  years  by  paying  at  the  end  of  successive 
years  20,  40,  30,  and  10  millions  (these  to  include  "  in- 
terest").  The  present  value  of  these  sums  is  66.321 
millions,  which  is  therefore  the  amount  of  the  loan  re- 
ceived from  the  syndicate.  This  sum  is  obtained  by 
adding  the  present  values  of  several  payments.  The 
present  value  of  20  millions,  due  one  year  hence,  is 

^°  =  19.418  millions. 
1.03 


and  of  40  millions,  due  two  years  hence,  is 

• ~ =  25.136  millious, 

(1.03)  (1.545) 

for  evidently  if  this  be  put  at  interest  for  one  year  at 


367]  Appreciation  and  Interest.  25 

3^,  and  the  next  at  541-%  it  will  amount  to  40  millions. 
Likewise  the  third  and  fourth  payments  have  present 
values  of 

-. ,,     ^°  ,, r  =  16.639  millions 

(i.03)(i.545)(i.i33) 

5.128  millions. 


(i.03)(i.545)(i.i33)(i.o8i5) 


The  sum  of  these  four  present  values  is  66.321  mil- 
lions. Now  if  we  compute  the  present  values  of  the 
four  payments  on  the  basis  of  a  uniform  rate  of  20.26% 
interest,  we  obtain  the  same  sum,  thus 

r=  16.631  millions 


(1.2026) 


40 


(1.2026^ 
30 


27.659 


^  =  17-250 
( 1. 2026)'' 

^°        =   4-781       " 
(r.2026)* 

Total,       =66.321       " 

The  separate  present  values  are  here  fictitious,  that  is, 
no  one  of  them  is  the  actual  present  selling  price  of  the 
future  payment  to  which  it  refers,  but  the  deviations  so 
offset  each  other  that  their  sum  is  the  actual  present 
selling  price  of  the  whole  set  of  future  payments.  It 
follows  from  principles  already  stated  that  the  debt, 
66.321  millions,  can  be  liquidated  by  precisely  the  same 
payments  (20,  40,  30  and  10  millions)  whether  the  in- 
terest is  reckoned  separately  at  3,  54^,  i3to",  ^^^  ^tot^ 
or  uniformly  at  20.26%.  In  fact  the  details  of  the  book- 
keeping in  the  two  cases  are  : 


26 


American  Economic  Association. 


[368 


At  3,  54i  i3T^ff.  StVc^- 

At  20.26%  uniformly. 

(In  Millions.) 

(In  Million.?.) 

I'^ter-  ^^o„„t 

Pay- 
ment. 

Prin- 
cipal. 

Inter- 
est. 

Amount. 

Pay- 
ment. 

Prin- 
cipal. 

Date 

In  I  year    . 
In  2  years  . 
In  3  years  . 
In  4  years  . 

1.99,      68.31 

26.33       74-64 

4-6i       39  25 

.75       10,00 

20.00 
40.00 
30.00 
10  00 

66.32 
48.31 
34-64 

9-25 
0.00 

13-44 
12. II 

645 
1. 68 

79-76 
71.87 
38-32 
10.00 

20.  on 
40.00 
30.00 
10.00 

66.32 

59-76 

3t-^7 

8.32 

0.00 

We  thus  see  that  20.26^  is  the  "average"  of  3,  54^, 
133^  and  S^^^^s  in  the  sense  that,  by  it,  the  same  pay- 
ments will  cancel  the  same  debt.  It  is  not  identical 
with  the  arithmetical  average,  which  is  19.74^. 

§3- 

Let  ns  suppose  that  the  rate  of  appreciation  of  one 
standard  in  terms  of  the  other  is  foreknown  to  be  a^  the 
first  year,  a.^  the  second  year,  a.,  the  third  year,  and  so 
on ;  also,  to  be  as  general  as  possible,  that  the  rates  of 
interest  in  both  standards  are  variable,  being  in  the  ap- 
preciating standard  i^  the  first  year,  i.,  the  second,  etc., 
and  in  the  depreciating  standard,  y^,  y^,  etc.  Let  the 
final  settlement  occur  in  n  years.  Then,  as  in  §  2,  we 
may  regard  the  contract  as  equivalent  to  a  series  of  one- 
year  contracts  successively  renewed  in  whole  or  in  part, 
the  difference  being  only  that  the  terms  are  all  made  in 
advance.  As  equation  (2)  applies  to  each  of  these  con- 
tracts, we  have 

I +yx =(!  +  «,)  (!  +  ?■,) 


(9) 


To  obtain  an  expression  for  the  average  rate  of  inter- 
est in  either  standard,  i.  <?.,  z  „  (ory  J,  we  require  a  given 
series  of  payments  Z?^,  Z>^,    .    .    .    Z>„  in  the  gold  standard 


369]  Appreciation  and  Interest.  27 

(or  their  equivalent  B^,  B.^^     .     .     .  B^^  in  the  silver 

standard).      The    aggregate    present  value    of     these 

payments,    reckoned  by  the  separate  rates  of  interest, 
^i^'^2^     .     ■    iiorjnJ,    .     .    yjis 


l+i,    '     (I  +  i,)  (  I  +  /J     ^  ^  (I  +  Zj  (I  +  tj  .   .  .   (I  +  4) 

(or  the  corresponding  expression  in  terms  of  j^'sand/'s). 
Now  the  "  average  "  rate  i ^^  must  be  such  that  if  applied 
to  the  same  set  of  payments  it  will  make  the  same  sum 
of  present  values  ;  that  is,  i^  is  determined  by 


1  +  4 '      (1  +  4)-  '  (i  +  4r 

(10) 

i  +  4^(i  +  4)(i  +  4)^      ^(i  +  4)(i  +  /j  •   •  (i+?j 

and  j\^  is  determined  by  the  corresponding  formula  in 
^'s  and  y  's. 

This  equation  has  only  one  real  and  positive  root  or 
value  of  i  ^.  It  can  readily  be  obtained  by  Horner's 
Method/  We  shall  call  z^  and /^^  the  "actuarial  aver- 
age" of  ?„  ?„  •  .  z;  and  of  /„  /„  .  .  /„  re- 
spectively.^ 

'  For,  h\  substituting  for -,  the  single  letter  x  and  for 


1  +  4  I  +  4> 

,  etc.,  the  letters  x^,  .tr„  etc.,  the  equation  becomes  : 

1  +  4 

D^x  +  D^x""-^  ■  ■  +D^x'^  =  D^x^-{-D^x^x^+  .  ■  +D^x^x^  .  .  x^. 
In  the  example  of  I  2,  the  equation  becomes  : 

20  .ar  +  40  ;r^  +  30  .ar^  +  ID  .ar*  =  66  321, 
the  required  root  of  which  is  x  =      .83155, 

which,  applied  to  ^^ ,  gives  j\^=^      .2026. 

I+7a 

*  I  +  4  reduces  to  the  "geometrical  average  "  of  i  +  4»  i  +  4)  ^^c. . 
when  Z?,  =  Z>,  =  .  •  =  D.-,  =  o. 


28  American  Economic  Association.  [37° 

§5. 

We  may  define  tlie  average  rate  of  appreciation  of  one 
of  the  two  standards  in  terms  of  the  other  as  that  rate 
which  would  connect  the  two  average  interest  rates  if 
the  latter  were  actual  (instead  of  averages  of  actual)  rates.  ^ 
That  is,  the  average  appreciation,  a,_^^  is  given  by  the 
equation 

or  a       -^iiJZ^?  (11) 

Thus  in  the  example  of   §1,  the  average  silver  interest 
is  20.26^  and  gold  interest  3^   so  that 

.2026   —   .0^  r„i, 

«a= , =  ■  1676, 

I  +  .03 
or  16.76^.  This  average  is  not  identical  with  the 
arithmetical  average  of  o,  50,  10  and  5^s,  which  would 
be  16.25%,  ^^*^^  i^  it  identical  with  that  rate  which  if 
uniform  would  result  in  four  years  in  the  same  diver- 
gence between  silver  and  gold  as  was  produced  by  the 
four  successive  rates  o,  50,  10  and  5/^s;  this  would  be 
14.70%.  For  the  statistical  purposes  of  Part  II.,  how- 
ever, the  latter  method  is  adopted  for  simplicity  and  is 
doubtless  correct  within  the  limit  of  error. 

§  6. 

It  may  seem  that  the  subject  of  this  chapter  can  have 
no  practical  application.  In  Part  II  we  shall  see  that 
this  is  not  the  case.  A  government  bond,  for  instance,  is 
a  promise  to  pay  a  specific  series  of  future  sums,  the 
price  of  the  bond  is  the  present  value  of  this  series  and 

^  It  may  be  proved  that  this  definition  of  a^,  satisfies  the  general 
condition  of  au  average,  viz.,  that  a^  reduces  to  a,,  a^,  etc.,  when  the 
latter  are  all  equal,  whether  z,,  i^,  etc.  {and  j\.j\,  etc.,)  be  all  equal 
or  not. 


37 1]  Appreciatio7i  and  hiterest.  29 

the  "  interest  realized  by  the  investor  "  as  computed  by 
actuaries  is  nothins:  more  nor  less  than  the  "  averao-e  " 
rate  of  interest  in  the  sense  above  defined.  Of  course 
the  investor  puts  no  specific  values  on  the  individual 
yearly  rates  of  interest  of  which  the  "interest  realized  " 
is  the  average,  but  that  this  interest  is  truly  an  average 
is  attested  both  by  the  comparative  stability  of  the  rate 
of  interest  realized  on  long  time  bonds  as  compared  with 
the  fluctuations  of  the  rate  of  interest  in  the  short  time 
money  market  ( a  stability  which  the  rate  realized  on  the 
bonds  does  not  possess  when  near  maturity^ )  and  by  the 
fact  that  interest  realized  on  a  very  long  bond,  say  50 
years,  is  often  lower  than  on  a  25  years'  bond.  This  is 
explainable  by  the  prevailing  opinion  that  interest  tends 
to  fall,  so  that  if  the  50  years'  investment  were  in  two 
successive  bonds  of  25  years  each,  the  interest  realized 
in  the  second  would  be  lower  than  in  the  first.  The 
"  actuarial  average  "  of  the  two  is  equal  to  the  interest 
realized  on  the  50  years'  bond. 

'  This  is  abundantly  verified  by  market  quotations,  as  is  also  the 
fact  that  the  interest  realized  to  him  who  buys  a  bond  and  sells  it 
again  in  a  short  time  is  even  more  variable  than  rates  on  money. 
Thus,  if  in  a  fortnight  ( in  which  no  interest  falls  due  )  the  bond  ad- 
vances y%,  the  speculator  realizes  at  the  rate  of  about  3%  per  annum  ; 
if  the  rise  is  %,  he  realizes  over  12%.  The  investor  who  holds  a  bond 
along  time  realizes  an  interest  which  is  an  "average  "  of  the  oscillat- 
ing rates  of  those  who  speculate  during  the  interim. 


CHAPTER  VI. 

ZERO  AND  NEGATIVE  INTEREST. 


Having  established  the  truth  and  generality  of  the 
principle  i  +/ =  (  i  +  <^)  (i  +  z"),  we  next  inquire  what 
limits,  if  any,  are  imposed  on  the  three  magnitudes 
y,  rt-,  i.  The  foregoing  equation  seems  to  require  that, 
when  the  appreciation  is  sufficiently  rapid,  the  rate  of 
interest  in  the  upward  moving  standard  should  be  zero 
or  negative.  Thus  if  a  =j\  the  equation  gives  us  i=  o. 
iVgain  if  «  >y  then  z  <  o.  For  instance,  if  /,  the  rate 
of  interest  in  wheat,  is  8  ^  and  if  gold  appreciates  rela- 
tively to  wheat  20^/0  per  annum,  we  have  i  -J- .08  := 
(i  +  .20)  (i  +  i)  whence  i=  —  .10 ;  that  is,  the  rate  of 
interest  in  gold  would  be  minus  10  fo  I 

Now  it  is  clear  that  negative  interest  is  impossible. 
Any  possessor  of  $100  of  gold  (or  its  equivalent  in  goods 
which  can  be  sold  for  gold)  would  hoard  the  gold  rather 
than  lend  it  at  a  loss.  That  is,  the  relation  z  <  o  is  im- 
possible and  therefore  also  «  >/  is  impossible.  Thus 
our  magnitudes  are  restricted  within  certain  limits,  viz., 

z  >  o 

(12) 

or,  in  words,  the  rate  of  interest  in  a  money  which  can 
be  hoarded  (without  trouble,  risk  or  expense)  can  never 
sink  below  zero  and  the  money  itself  can  never  undergo 
an  expected  appreciation  (relatively  to  another  standard) 
greater  than  the  rate  of  interest  in  that  standard. 


373]  Appreciation  and  Interest.  31 

§2. 

This  last  result  will  not  seem  mysterious  when  we  re- 
flect that  the  same  cause,  viz.,  hoarding,  which  prevents 
the  interest  from  being  negative  also  checks  the  expected 
rate  of  appreciation.  An  example  will  make  this  clear. 
It  is  a  familiar  fact  that  the  expected  rate  of  appreciation 
of  real  estate  (relatively  to  money)  can  never  be  more 
rapid  than  the  rate  of  interest  (in  money).  If  the  latter 
is  5^,  the  (money)  value  of  land  can  never  advance 
faster  than  5  ^  per  annum  except  when  that  advance  is 
unforeseen. 

The  explanation  is  simple.  If  it  were  foreknown  that 
certain  land  values  would  rise  10^,  owners  would  be 
able  to  make  twice  as  much  by  holding  as  by  selling 
and  investing  the  proceeds  at  5^.  The  land  would  be 
hoarded.  This  decreases  the  supply  and  sends  up  the 
price  until  it  is  within  at  least  sfooi  the  expected  sell- 
ing price  one  year  hence.  It  thus  happens  that  holding 
city  lots  for  speculation  comes  to  be  regarded  as  a  regular 
investment  from  which  the  same  return  is  to  be  ex- 
pected as  from  investing  in  a  productive  enterprise.  The 
same  could  be  said  of  wheat,  cotton,  or  other  specula- 
tion. Hoarding  money  is  but  a  particular  form  of 
"holding  for  a  rise."  In  all  cases  the  process  tends  to 
lessen  the  rise — not  to  obliterate  it  but  to  make  it  equal 
to  the  rate  of  interest  (in  the  standard  in  which  the  rise 
itself  is  measured). 

In  the  case  of  appreciating  money  we  saw  that,  of  the 
two  conditions  i~  o  and  a  ^j\  the  first  was  the  more  ob- 
vious, while  in  the  case  of  appreciating  real  estate  the 
second  was  the  more  obvious.  The  reason  is  that  in 
both  cases  we  are  accustomed  to  think  in  terms  of 
money.     We  say,   "  the  rate  of  interest  cannot  be  nega- 


32  American  Economic  Association.  [374 

tive,"  "  the  expected  rise  of  real  estate  cannot  exceed 
the  rate  of  interest,"  but,  as  we  have  seen,  each  of  these 
statements  implies  another.  It  may  strike  the  reader  as 
a  new  idea  that  land  speculation  presents  an  actually 
existinp-  case  of  zero  interest.  And  yet  this  is  undoiibt- 
edlv  so,  if  we  take  as  our  standard  an  acre  of  speculative 
land.  The  land  speculator  is  "  making  money  "  but  not 
"  making  land."  His  100  acres  remains  100  acres.  We 
could  even  imagine  all  loan  contracts  translated  from 
"  dollars  "  into  "  acres  "  (though  still  keeping  money  as 
the  mcdiitni).  K  debt  of  100  "  acres  "  would  be  liquid- 
ated one  year  hence  by  100  "  acres  "  and  interest  would 
be  nil.  There  is  no  intrinsic  reason  why  this  same  zero 
interest  (for  absolutely  safe  loans)  might  not  sometime 
be  true  of  money,  and  this  without  implying  any  change 
in  the  abundance  of  capital. 

§3. 

It  is  important  to  emphasize  the  fact  that  these  limits 
imposed  on  the  magnitudes  i  and  a  come  from  the  possi- 
bility of  hoarding  money  without  loss.  If  the  money  were 
a  perishable  commodity,  such  as  fruit,  the  limit  would  be 
pushed  into  the  region  of  negative  quantities.  One  can 
imagine  a  loan  based  on  strawberries  or  peaches  con- 
tracted in  summer  and  payable  in  winter  with  negative 
interest.^  Or,  again,  we  may  define  a  "  dollar"  as  con- 
sisting of  a  constantly  increasing  number  of  grains  of 
gold.^  If  the  weight  doubles  yearly,  such  "  dollars" 
cannot  be  hoarded  without  growing  fewer  with  time, 
and  if  interest  was  previously  5  ^  it  will  now  be  minus 
^iVz^oy  for  he  who  borrows  $100  (2580  grains)  to-day 

iCf.  Bolim-Bawerk,  "  Positive  Theory  of  Capital,"  pp.  252,  297. 
2  Such  a  definition  for  either  the  gold  or  silver  "  pound"  is  implied 
in  Professor  Foxwell's  proposal  for  a  "  climbing"  ratio. 


375]  Appreciation  a^id  Interest.  33 

will  pay  back  I52.50  (2709  grains)  one  year  hence. 
Again  we  find  a  real  example  by  recurring  to  land 
speculation.  Since  to  hold  land  usually  involves  paying 
taxes  upon  it,  the  rate  of  interest  in  terms  of  such 
"  acres"  is  often,  in  actual  fact,  negative. 

§4. 

In  this  connection,  an  apparent  difficulty  needs  to  be 
explained.  If  gold  should  appreciate  up  to  the  maxi- 
mum limit  so  that  the  interest  rate  were  zero  for  safe 
loans,  would  not  all  investment  cease  ?  What  object 
would  a  capitalist  have  in  investing  when  he  could  gain 
as  much  by  hoarding  ?  Nothing  could  be  more  natural 
than  the  fallacy  here  involved  and  we  ought  not  to  be 
surprised  on  finding  it  among  the  arguments  of  certain 
bimetallists.  For  example,  the  Free  Coinage  Conven- 
tion at  Memphis,  Tenn.,  a  year  ago,  adopted  the  follow- 
ing resolution  :  "  The  demonetization  of  either  silver  or 
gold  means  a  fall  in  the  prices  of  commodities,  a  dimi- 
nution of  the  profits  of  legitimate  business,  a  continuing 
increase  in  the  burden  of  debts,  with  consequent  hard 
times,  idle  labor  and  idle  capital.,  the  increasing  value 
of  money  promising  a  surer  rettirn  to  a  hoarded  dollar 
than  to  an  invested  oney 

The  error  here  contained  is  the  ancient  confusion  of 
capital  and  money.  It  is  true  that  a  limited^  amount 
of  gold  would  be  withdrawn  and  hoarded,  but  this 
would  not  check  the  investment  of  capital  any  more 
than  the  similar  withdrawal  of  so  much  copper.  If  a 
hoarded  dollar  yields  a  "  sure  return,"  a  hoarded  dollar^ s 

'  As  in  the  case  of  land,  the  hoarding  would  reach  its  limit  when  it 
had  raised  the  value  (marginal  utility)  of  present  money  up  to  the 
present  value  of  future  money.     Hoarding  beyond  this  point  would 
bring  loss. 
3 


34  American  Economic  Association.  [.37^ 

worth  of  goods  as  surely  bri?tgs  loss.  The  possessors  of 
stocks  of  cotton  or  grain,  machinery  or  ships,  the  prices 
of  which  are  falling,  have  no  disposition  to  keep  them 
unemployed.  A  retail  dealer  fills  his  store  with  carpets 
and  gives  the  wholesale  dealer  his  note  for  three  months. 
He  is  said  to  borrow  "  money"  but  he  really  borrows 
carpets.  He  may  pay  no  (money)  interest  and  yet  the 
wholesaler  gains  by  the  loan.  He  is  saved  a  loss  in  the 
(money)  value  of  the  carpets  which  he  would  have  in- 
curred had  he  failed  to  get  rid  of  them.  In  terms  of 
carpets  he  may  be  making  5^.  Similar  considerations 
apply  when  the  loan  is  negotiated  through  a  third  party, 
as  a  bank,  and  apply  in  fact  to  all  forms  of  loans  and 
investments.  But  the  case  supposed  is  so  highly  hypo- 
thetical and  the  error  involved  has  been  so  often  ex- 
plained ^  that  no  further  treatment  of  it  seems  necessary 
here.  However  turned  or  twisted  and  from  whatever 
point  of  view  examined,  lending  "  money"  at  no  per 
cent,  may  under  certain  circumstances  be  a  very  profita- 
ble transaction.  It  goes  without  saying  that  the  fore- 
going conclusions  apply  only  to  "  pure"  or  "  net" 
interest.  That  part  of  market  interest  representing 
risk,  and  that  part  representing  commissions  for  transact- 
ing the  business  of  lending  and  borrowing  would  not 
disappear. 

^E.  g.  F.  A.  Walker,  "Money.."  (New  York,  187S),  p.  94. 


PART  II.     FACTS. 
CHAPTER  VII. 

INTRODUCTION. 


No  study  of  the  relation  between  appreciation  and  in- 
terest would  be  complete  without  verification  by  facts. 
In  imaginary  illustrations,  such  as  those  used  in  Part  I, 
it  is  easy  to  make  calculations  agree  to  the  last  decimal 
place ;  but  the  figures  in  which  we  are  really  interest- 
ed must  come  from  actual  market  quotations.  Through 
these  alone  can  we  test  our  assumption  that  foresight  in 
regard  to  the  appreciation  or  depreciation  of  money  ac- 
tually exists. 

At  the  outset  the  question  arises,  how  can  a  merchant 
be  said  to  foresee  the  appreciation  of  money  ?  Appreci- 
ation is  a  subtle  conception.  Few  business  men  have 
any  clear  ideas  about  it.  Economists  disagree  as  to  its  def- 
inition, and  statisticians  as  to  its  measurement.  If  you 
ask  a  merchant  whether  he  takes  account  of  appreciation, 
he  will  say  he  never  thinks  of  it,  that  he  always  regards 
a  dollar  as  a  dollar.  Other  things  may  change  in  terms 
of  money,  but  money  itself  he  is  accustomed  to  think 
of  as  the  one  fixed  thing.  But  though  we  do  ordinarily 
regard  the  value  of  a  dollar  as  a  fixed  magnitude,  this 
does  not  really  prevent  our  taking  account  of  its  changes. 
In  our  daily  life  we  think  of  the  earth  as  fixed,  but  we 
virtually  take  account  of  its  rotation  whenever  we  speak 
of  sunrise  or  sunset.  During  a  period  of  inflation  the 
ordinary  man  conceives  the  premium  on  gold  as  a  rise  of 


^6  American  Economic  Association.  [378 

gold  not  a  fall  of  money.  But  if  he  takes  account  of 
rising  wages  and  rising  prices  he  arrives  at  the  same  re- 
sults as  if  he  had  thought  of  falling  money.  We  need 
not  ascribe  to  the  practical  man  any  knowledge  of 
"  absolute  "  appreciation,  but  whatever  absolute  apprecia- 
tion is,  it  is  included,  though  unseparated,  in  the  practical 
man's  forecast  in  terms  of  money  of  all  the  economic 
elements  which  concern  him — prices  of  his  product, 
cost  of  living,  wages  of  his  workmen,  and  so  forth.  If 
he  expects  falling  prices  and  rising  wages,  as  is  often  the 
case,  he  may  be  said  to  foresee  an  appreciation  of  gold 
as  defined  by  the  ordinary  bimetallist  and  at  the  same 
time  a  depreciation  as  measured  by  difficulty  of  attain- 
ment. What  is  more,  he  takes  account  of  the  relative 
importance,  as  affecting  himself,  of  the  various  changes 
which  he  expects,  and  not  of  their  relative  importance 
in  the  elaborate  averages  of  the  statistician,  averages 
which  may  emphasize  some  commodity  or  some  labor 
whose  fluctuations  have  absolutely  no  concern  for  him. 
His  effort  is  not  to  predict  the  index  numbers  of  Sauer- 
beck or  Conrad,  but  so  to  foresee  his  own  economic  fu- 
ture as  to  make  reasonably  correct  decisions,  and  in  par- 
ticular to  know  what  he  is  about  when  contracting  a  loan. 
If  gold  appreciates  in  such  a  way  or  in  such  a  sense  that 
he  expects  a  shrinking  margin  of  profit,  he  will  be  cau- 
tious about  borrowing  unless  interest  falls  ;  and  this  very 
unwillingness  to  borrow,  lessening  the  demand  in  the 
"  money  market,"  will  bring  interest  down.  Further 
explanation  of  this  process  is  postponed  to  Chapter  X. 


Before  proceeding  to  specific  statistics,  it  is  important 
to  emphasize  the  broad  fact  that  in  general,  business  fore- 
sight exists  and  that  the  accuracy  and  power  of  this  fore- 


379]  Appreciation  and  Interest.  37 

sight  is  greater  today  than  ever  before.  It  is  one  of  the 
distinguishing  marks  of  modern  business.  Multitudes 
of  trade  journals  and  investors'  reviews  have  their  sole 
reason  for  existence  in  supplying  data  on  which  to  base 
prediction.  Every  chance  for  gain  is  eagerly  watched. 
An  active  and  intelligent  speculation  is  constantly  going 
on  which,  so  far  as  it  does  not  consist  of  fictitious 
and  gambling  transactions,  performs  a  well  known 
and  provident  function  for  society.  Is  it  reasonable 
to  believe  that  foresight,  which  is  the  general  rule,  has 
an  exception  as  applied  to  falling  or  rising  prices  ?  Or, 
if  so,  can  the  academic  bimetallist  assume  himself  pos- 
sessed of  a  foresight  of  which  he  says  the  practical  man 
is  incapable  ?  It  is  the  practical  man's  business  to  fore- 
see. It  is  he  who  first  gathers  the  facts  and  statistics  on 
which  forecasts  must  be  based.  It  is  he  who  watches 
the  trend  of  past  price  movements  and  notes  the  slight- 
est signs  of  a  change.  And  it  is  in  his  trade  journals 
that  we  find  the  first  discussions  of  the  probable  effect  of 
gold  discoveries  or  silver  legislation  on  prices  and  trade. 
The  theorist  can  aid  in  these  predictions  only  by  sup- 
plying or  correcting  the  principles  on  which  they  are 
constructed. 


CHAPTER   VIII. 

GOLD  AND  PAPER. 
§1. 

General  evidence  that  an  expected  cliange  in  the  value 
of  money  has  an  effect  on  the  rate  of  interest  can  be  ob- 
tained from  several  sources.  Municipalities  often  find 
they  can  sell  gold  bonds  at  better  terms  than  currency 
or  coin  bonds.  The  very  desire  of  lenders  to  insert  a 
gold  clause  in  their  contracts  is  strong  proof  that  they 
are  willing  to  yield  something  for  it.  This  was  strik- 
ingly shown  in  California^  during  the  war  inflation 
period,  where  for  a  time,  gold  contracts  could  not  be  en- 
forced and  in  consequence  interest  rates  were  very  high. 

During  a  period  of  progressive  paper  inflation  it  is  also 
true  that  interest  is  high  even  when  the  contract  is 
drawn  on  a  paper  basis.  As  we  shall  see  at  a  later  stage, 
this  was  partially  true  during  the  civil  war,  though  its 
effect  was  not  very  pronounced  owing  to  the  over  san- 
guine hopes  of  an  early  termination  of  the  war  and  a 
return  to  a  specie  basis.  It  was  also  true  during  the 
currency  troubles  in  the  thirties.  Raguet  wrote  : "  "In 
the  six  months  before  the  suspension  of  ^2>7i  although 
the  amount  of  the  currency  was  greater  than  it  had  ever 
been  before  in  the  United  States,  yet  the  scarcity  of 
money  was  so  great  that  it  commanded  from  i^o  to  3  ^ 
per  month."  It  would  be  unsafe  to  found  much  infer- 
ence on  these  facts.     Their  significance  may  be  partly 

^  Bernard  Moses,  "  Legal  Tender  Notes  in  California,"  Quarterly 
Journal  of  Economics,  October,  1892,  p.  15. 

-"  Currency  and  Banking,"  (1839),  p.  139;  alsoSumner,  "  History;  of 
Banking,"  (1896),  p.  264. 


38 1] 


Appreciation  a7id  Interest. 


39 


or  wholly  different.  But  they  raise  a  presumption  in 
favor  of  the  theory  here  advanced  and  against  the  theory 
that  the  rate  of  interest  is  lowered  by  inflation  of  the 
currency. 


A  definite  test  must  be  sought  where  two  standards 
are  simultaneously  used.  An  excellent  case  of  this  kind 
is  supplied  by  two  kinds  of  United  States  bonds,  one 
payable  in  coin  and  the  other  in  currency.  From  the 
prices  which  these  bonds  fetch  in  the  market  it  is  pos- 
sible to  calculate  the  interest  realized  to  the  investor. 
The  currency  bonds  are  known  as  currency  sixes  and 
mature  in  1898  and  1899.  The  coin  bonds  selected  for 
comparison  are  the  4^5  of  1907.  The  following  table 
gives  the  rates  of  interest  realized  in  the  two  standards 
together  with  the  premium  on  gold. 


RATES  OF  INTEREST  REALIZED  FROM 

DATES    MENTIONED 

TO   MATURITy.i 

Price  of 

Coin. 

Currency. 

Coin. 

Currency. 

6.4 

Gold. 

Jan., 

1870  . 

5-4 

119. 9 

Jan.. 

1879    •    • 

1     3-7 

4-5 

July. 

1870  . 

5-8 

5-1 

112. 2 

Jan., 

1880   . 

i     3-8 

4.0 

Jan  , 

187T  . 

6.0 

5-3 

I  TO  8 

Jan., 

1 881 

•     3-3 

3-4 

July, 

1871  . 

5-8 

50 

113. 2 

Jan., 

1882 

1     3-0 

3-5 

Jan., 

1872  . 

5-3 

4-9 

109.5 

Jan. , 

1SS3 

2.9 

3-3 

July. 

1872  . 

56 

5.0 

113-9 

Jan., 

T884 

\     2.6 

2.9 

Jan., 

1873  • 

5-7 

5-1 

III. 9 

May, 

1SS5 

1     ^-7 

2.7 

July, 

1S73  • 

5-4 

50 

"5-3 

Jan., 

t886 

1     2.6 

2.6 

Jan., 

1874  • 

5-0 

5-0 

110.3 

Jan., 

1887 

2.3 

2.6 

July, 

1874  . 

50 

4-9 

T10.7 

Mar. 

t888 

2.3 

29 

Jan., 

1875  • 

5-1 

47 

112. 6 

Jan., 

1889 

2.2 

2.6 

July, 

1875  • 

51 

4-4 

1 17.0 

May, 

1S90 

2.T 

2.6 

Jan., 

1876  . 

4-7 

4.4 

112. 9 

July, 

189T 

2.4 

3-0 

July, 

1876  . 

4-5 

4.2 

112.3 

Jan., 

1892 

i       '-^ 

3-1 

Jan., 

1S77  . 

45 

4.4 

107.0 

Mar. 

1S93 

i       2.8 

3-1 

July, 

1877  . 

4.4 

4-3 

105.4 

Nov. 

,  1894 

2.7 

3-5 

Jan., 

1878 

50 

4.6 

102.8 

Aug. 

,1895 

2.8 

3-6 

July, 

1878  . 

3.9 

4.4 

TOO.  7 

Aug. 

,  1896 

3.2 

4-3 

^This  table  has  been  obtained  by  the  aid  of  the  usual  brokers'  bond 
tables.  In  the  case  of  currency  bcir.ds,  it  was  only  necessary  to  deduct 
accrued  interest  (if  any)  from  the  quoted  price  and  look  in  the  table 
for  the  interest  which  corresponds  to  the  price  so  found  and  the  num- 


40  American  Economic  Association.  ^  [382 

Several  points  in  this  table  deserve  notice.  The  quo- 
tations for  1894,  '95,  '96  show  a  considerably  higher  rate 
of  interest  in  the  currency  standard  than  in  the  coin  stand- 
ard as  well  as  a  higher  rate  in  both  standards  than  in 
previous  years.  The  difference  is  between  2.7^  and 
3.5^  in  1894,  and  between  3.2^  and  4.3^  in  1896. 
Both  the  increase  and  the  wedging  apart  of  the  two  rates 
are  explainable  as  effects  of  the  free  silver  proposal  and 
its  incorporation  (July  1896)  in  the  platform  of  the 
Democratic  party.  A  free  silver  law  v^^ould  certainly  re- 
duce the  value  of  returns  from  currency  bonds  and  possi- 
bly also  of  those  from  coin  bonds.  If  the  mere  dread  of 
inflation  has  this  effect,  it  might  be  supposed  that,  dur- 
ing the  period  of  actual  inflation,  the  discrimination  in 
favor  of  coin  bonds  would  be  even  greater.  But  we  find 
the  exact  opposite  to  be  true.  In  1870  the  investor 
made  6.4^  in  gold  but  was  willing  to  accept  a  return  of 
only  5.4^  in  currency.  This  fact  becomes  intelligible 
in  the  light  of  the  theory  which  has  been  explained.  It 
meant  the  hope  of  resumption.  Just  because  paper  was 
so  depreciated  there  was  a  prospect  of  a  great  rise  in  its 
value.  It  was  not  until  1878  when  the  prospect  of  a 
further  rise  disappeared  that  the  relative  position  of  the 
two  rates  of  interest  was  reversed.  After  resumption  in 
1879  the  two  remained  very  nearly  equal  for  several 
years  until  recent  fears  of  inflation  again  produced  a 
divergence. 

ber  of  years  to  maturity.  In  the  case  of  gold  bonds,  since  the  quota- 
tions are  given  in  currency,  it  is  necessary  to  divide  the  quoted  price 
by  the  price  of  gold  in  order  to  obtain  their  price  in  gold  {i.  e., 
"coin")  and  then  proceed  as  above  indicated.  The  quotations  of 
prices  of  bonds  and  gold  are  the  "opening"  prices  for  the  months 
named  and  are  taken  from  the  Financial  Reviezv,  1895,  the  Commer- 
cial and  Fitiancial  Chronicle,  the  (New  York)  Bankers'  Magazine 
and  the  Bankers'  Almanac.  After  1SS4,  January  quotations  were  not 
always  available. 


383]  AppreciatioJi  and  Interest.  41 

§3- 

We  have  found  so  far  that  the  facts  agree  with  the 
theory  previously  laid  down.  But  it  is  necessary  further 
to  inquire  how  close  is  this  agreement.  For  this  pur- 
pose, the  figures  just  given  are  of  little  value.  They 
represent  the  rates  of  interest  realized  for  the  periods  be- 
tween the  dates  named  and  the  times  at  which  the  bonds 
mature.  These  periods  are  not  the  same  for  the  two 
bonds.  As  has  been  explained  such  a  rate  of  interest  is 
a  sort  of  average  of  the  rates  of  interest  for  the  individual 
years  of  the  periods  in  question.  Thus,  in  the  foregoing 
table,  the  rate  of  interest  in  currency  opposite  January, 
1870,  is  5.4^.  This  is  the  rate  realized  between  1870  and 
1899.  It  is  a  sort  of  average  of,  say,  the  rate  realized  be- 
tween 1870  and  1879  and  between  1879  and  1899.  As 
we  shall  see  the  former  was  6.3^  and  the  latter,  4-5/^. 

It  is  clear  that  we  must  seek  the  rates  of  interest  in 
the  two  standards  for  the  same  periods.  In  the  follow- 
ing table  the  periods  selected  terminate  on  Jan.  i,  1879, 
the  date  of  resumption  of  specie  payments.  We  may 
say,  to  fix  our  ideas,  that  the  figures  represent  the  rate  of 
interest  realized  to  investors  who  buy  the  bonds  at  the 
dates  mentioned  and  sell  them  on  January  i,  1879 ;  but 
it  is  obviously  unnecessary  to  consider  the  bonds  as  ac- 
tually either  bought  or  sold,  but  only  as  owned.  This 
is  no  nevv^  use  of  terms.  Business  men  reckon  securities 
in  their  assets  at  their  market  prices  and  if  these  prices 
rise  or  fall  they  count  themselves  as  gainers  or  losers. 
This  gain  (or  loss)  added  to  the  annual  interest  receipts 
and  properly  distributed  over  the  time  considered  gives 
the  rate  of  interest  realized. 


42 


American  Economic  Association. 


[3S4 


RATES  OF  INTEREST  REALIZED   FROM   DATES  MENTIONED   TO   JAN- 
UARY I,  1879,  (Date  of  Resumption'). 


Coin. 

Currency. 

Appreciation  of  Currency  in  Gold. 

Expected. 

Actual. 

j 

i 

a 

January,  1S70.  .    .         q.i 

6.3 

.8 

2.1 

July,   1S70  .    . 

6.2 

5-7 

•5 

1.4 

January,  1871 . 

6.7 

63 

•4 

1-3 

July,  1S71 

6.4 

5-7 

•  7 

1.8 

January,  1S72 . 

5-9 

5-7 

.2 

1-3 

July,   1S72    . 

6.2 

5-7 

•5 

2  1 

January,  1873 • 

6.5 

62 

.3 

2.0 

July.  i'S73  •    ■ 

6.2 

6.0 

.2 

2.8 

January,  1S74. 

5.6 

6   T 

—.5 

2.T 

July.   1874   .    . 

5-7 

5-8 

2.4 

Fanuary,  1875  • 

6.0 

5-4 

!6 

3-1 

July,   1875    •    . 

6.1 

4.2 

1.8 

4-9 

January,  1876. 

5-4 

41 

1.2 

43 

July,  1876  .    . 

5-2 

2.4 

2.7 

4.9 

January,  1877 . 

5-5 

4.0 

1.4 

3-5 

July,  1 87 7   .    . 

5.7 

3-1 

2.5 

3.6 

January,  1878. 

8.2 

6.0 

2, 1 

2.8 

July,  1878  .    . 

4.8 

2.6 

2,1 

1.4 

'  Since  the  figures  in  this  table  represent  the  rales  of  interest  which 
will  render  the  "  present  value,"  at  the  date  of  purchase,  of  all  the 
future  benefits  to  January,  1879,  equal  to  the  purchase  price,  they  can 
be  calculated  by  Horuer's  method  as  indicated  in  Chapter  V.  But  the 
method  which  has  been  adopted  is  less  laborious,  as  it  ena1)les  us  to 
use  the  bond  tallies.  It  can  best  be  explained  by  an  example.  The 
opening  price,  January,  1870,  of  currency  6's  was  109)^,  and  January, 
1879,  ^^9/i,  which  require  no  correction  for  accrued  interest.  Our 
problem  is,  if  a  man  spends  ^109"/^  in  1870  and  receives  |ii9><  in 
1879  with  $6  per  annum  (semi-annually)  in  the  meantime,  what  rate 
of  interest  does  he  realize?  Now  it  is  clear  that  the  answer  is  the 
same  if  all  the  benefits  and  sacrifices  involyed  are  doubled  or  halved 
or  increased  or  decreased  in  an}'  common  ratio.  Let  us  then  divide 
them  all  by  i.icjyi-  Then  I91.3  would  be  paid  in  1870  for  |;ioo  due  in 
1879,  and  ^5.02  per  annum  in  the  meantime.  That  is,  the  interest 
realized  is  exactly  as  if  the  bond  were  a  5.02%  bond  maturing  in  1879 
and  bought  at  91.3  in  1870.  This  can  readily  be  obtained  from  the 
bond  tables  by  interpolating  between  the  figures  for  a  5%  and  a  5)4% 
bond  purchased  at  91.3  and  having  9  years  to  run.  For  a  5%  bond 
we  obtain  6.28%,  and  for  a  5}4%  bond,  6.81%.  Hence  for  a  5.02% 
bond  the  result  is  6,30%,  or  6.3%,  The  third  column  gives  what  may 
be  called  the  expected  rate  of  appreciation  of  currency  in  terms  of 
gold,  that  is,  that  rate  of  appreciation   which   would  have   made  the 


385]  Appreciation  and  Intej^est.  43 

From  this  table  we  see  that  the  interests  realized  for 
the  period,  January,  1870  to  January,  1879,  were,  in  coin, 
7.1^,  and  in  currency,  6.3%,  which,  according  to  the 
formula  i  +  7  =  ( i  +  z )  ( i  +  <« ),  gives  a  rate  of  appre- 
ciation of  .8%.  This  may  be  called  the  "  expected  ap- 
preciation ".  The  actual  rate  of  appreciation  was  2.1%. 
That  is,  the  estimated  appreciation  was  about  two-fifths 
of  the  appreciation  as  it  really  turned  out.  Thus  those 
who  held  currency  sixes  had  the  better  investment.  In 
fact  it  is  w^ell  known  that  many  speculators  grew  rich  by 
exchanging  gold  bonds  for  currency  bonds  at  this  time. 
The  table  shows  the  same  misjudgment  in  July,  1870, 
January,  1871,  and  July,  1871.  From  then  to  July, 
1874,  the  outlook  for  resumption  grew  gloomy,  due  no 
doubt  to  the  strong  greenback  sentiment.  The  inflation 
bill  of  1874  actually  produced  a  prospect  of  negative 
appreciation,  i,  e.^  depreciation.  This  bill  was  vetoed  by 
President  Grant,  and  in  December  of  that  year  the  bill 
for  resumption  was  passed  by  the  Senate.  Accordingly 
January,  1875,  opened  with  a  more  hopeful  estimate. 
The  bill  became  law  on  the  14th  of  January  and  there 
was  an  immediate  rise  in  the  "  expected  "  appreciation 
which,  from  then  on,  averaged  2%.  But  during  the 
same  period  the  actual  appreciation  from  the  dates  named 

two  interest  rates  equally  profitable.  It  is  obtained  from  the  formula 
I  +y=  (i  -I-  ?■)  (i  +  «)•  The  last  column  gives  the  actual  rate  of  ap- 
preciation between  the  dates  mentioned  and  January  i,  1879.  This 
is  calculated  from  the  quoted  prices  of  gold.  Thus  the  opening  price 
of  gold  January,  1870,  was  119.9,  and  January,  1879,  ^oo-  Hence 
currency  appreciated  in  nine  years  in  the  ratio  100  to  119.9,  which  is 
at  the  race  of  2.1%  per  annum.  If  the  appreciation  proceeded  uni- 
formly this  method  would  be  strictly  correct.  As  it  is,  a  more  elabo- 
rate method  would  be  required,  in  accordance  with  the  principles  ex- 
plained in  Chapter  V,  to  take  account  fully  of  the  fluctuations  of  the 
annual  appreciation.  But  for  our  present  purposes,  and  for  results 
worked  out  to  but  one  decimal  place,  the  simpler  method  here 
adopted  is  sufficiently  correct. 


44  American  Econoviic  Association.  [386 

to  January,  1S79,  averaged  3.6%,  so  that  even  after  the 
government  promised  resumption,  investors  and  specula- 
tors did  not  put  implicit  confidence  in  that  promise,  the 
"expected"  appreciation  being  only  a  little  more  than 
half  the  actual  appreciation.  This  corresponds  to  the 
well  known  fact  that  the  resumption  act  was  then  looked 
upon  as  a  political  manoeuvre,  likely  to  be  repealed. 


It  should  be  observed  that  the  method  employed  to 
determine  the  rate  of  interest  realized  is  open  to  oiie 
danger.  It  correctly  represents  the  rate  of  interest  act- 
ually realized  between  tw^o  dates,  but,  unless  the  later  of 
the  two  dates  is  maturity,  it  does  not  necessarily  repre- 
sent the  rate  of  interest  expected  at  the  first  date.  The 
investor  could  not  know  in  January,  1870,  what  the  price 
of  bonds  would  be  in  January,  1879,  unless  the  bonds 
matured  at  that  time.  To  compare,  in  1870,  the  relative 
advantages  of  coin  and  currency  bonds  for  the  period 
1870-79,  a  forecast  was  necessary,  not  only  of  the  rela- 
tion of  currency  to  gold,  but  also  of  the  prices  of  the  two 
bonds  in  1879.  These  prices  in  turn  depend  on  a  new 
forecast  made  in  1879.  It  follows  that  a  mistake  in  this 
forecast  of  1879  ^^^  embodied  in  the  prices  of  that  year 
wall  affect  the  rate  of  interest  realized  between  1870  and 
1879  in  the  same  manner  as  a  mistake  of  the  opposite 
kind  in  the  forecast  of  1870. 

But  in  most  cases  the  method  given  is  sufficiently 
exact.  For,  although  in  1870  it  would  have  been  im- 
possible to  predict  exactly  the  prices  of  the  two  bonds  in 
1879,  yet  it  can  usually  be  depended  upon  that  any  great 
change  in  price  is  apt  to  affect  both  alike  (provided  they 
have   approximately   the  same   time   to  run)  and  thus 


387]  Appreciation  and  Interest. 


45 


eliminates  itself  for  the  most  part  in  the  comparison. 
For  this  reason  it  is  clearly  better  to  take  bonds  whose 
dates  of  maturity  approximately  correspond,  in  order 
that  any  abnormal  influence  in  1879  may  affect  both 
alike,  than  to  take,  for  instance,  currency  sixes  of  1899 
and  coin  bonds  of  1881. 


48  American  Economic  Association.  [390 

From  this  table  it  will  be  seen  that  the  rates  realized 
to  investors  in  bonds  of  the  two  standards  differed  but 
slightly  until  1875,  when  the  fall  of  Indian  exchange 
began.  The  average  difference  before  1875  was  .2^ 
while  the  average  difference  since  1875  has  been  .7^, 
or  more  than  three  times  as  much. 

From  1884  exchange  fell  much  more  rapidly  than  be- 
fore, and  the  difference  in  the  two  rates  of  interest  rose 
accordingly,  amounting  in  one  year  to  i.i^.  Since 
the  two  bonds  were  issued  hy  the  same  government, 
possess  the  same  degree  of  security,  are  quoted  side  by 
side  in  the  same  market  and  are  in  fact  similar  in  all 
important  respects  except  in  the  standard  in  which  the}- 
are  expressed,  the  results  afford  substantial  proof  that 
the  fall  of  exchange  (after  it  once  began)  was  discounted 
in  advance.  Of  course  investors  did  not  form  perfectly 
definite  estimates  of  the  future  fall,  but  the  fear  of  a  fall 
predominated  in  varying  degrees  over  the  hope  of  a  rise. 

The  year  1890  was  one  of  great  disturbance  in  ex- 
changes, the  average  for  the  first  six  months  being  17.6 
and  for  the  last  six  months  19.3.  The  gold  price  of 
the  silver  bonds  rose  from  an  average  for  the  first  six 
months  of  73.8  to  83.5  for  the  last  six  months,  but  the 
rise  in  their  silver  price  was  only  from  100.6  to  103.7, 
showing  that  the  increase  of  confidence  in  the  "  future 
of  silver"  was  not  great  and  in  fact  only  reduced  the 
disparity  in  the  interest  from  i.o  to  .8^. 

This  great  rise  in  exchange  and  the  slight  revival  in 
silver  securities  occurred  simultaneously  with  the  pas- 
sage of  the  Sherman  act  of  July,  1890,  by  which  the 
United  States  was  to  purchase  four  and  a  half  million 
ounces  of  silver  per  month.  There  can  be  little  doubt 
that  the  disturbance  was  due  in  some  measure  to  the 
operation  or  expected  operation  of  that  law. 


39 1]  Appreciation  and  Interest.  49 

This  is  not  the  only  case  in  which  the  relative  prices  of 
rupee  paper  and  gold  bonds  were  probably  affected  by  po- 
litical action.  The  smallest  difference  (since  1874)  in 
the  tw^o  rates  of  interest  occurs  in  1878,  which  was  the  year 
of  the  Bland  act  and  the  first  international  monetary 
conference. 

After  the  closure  of  the  Indian  mints  on  June  26,  1893, 
exchange  rose  from  14.7  to  15.9,  the  gold  price  of  rupee 
paper  from  62  to  70  and  consequently  its  rupee  price 
from  101.2  to  105.7. 

§  2. 

The  preceding  comparisons  serve  to  establish  the  in- 
fluence of  the  divergence  between  the  standards  on  the 
rates  of  interest,  but  afford  no  measure  of  that  influence. 
The  rates  of  interest  which  have  been  deduced  for  gold 
bonds  were  the  rates  realized  if  the  bonds  were  held  to 
maturity.  The  rupee  bond  had  no  fixed  date  of  matur- 
ity and  had  to  be  treated  as  a  perpetual  annuity,  although 
it  differed  from  such  an  annuity  in  being  terminable  by 
the  government  at  par  on  three  months'  notice. 

In  order  to  measure  the  extent  to  which  the  fall  of  silr 
ver  was  allowed  for  by  investors,  it  is  necessary  to  exam- 
ine the  rates  realized  during  specified  periods.  The  fol- 
lowing table  gives  the  rates  realized  between  the  first 
five  and  the  last  five  years  of  the  period  of  falling  ex- 
change. 


50 


American  Economic  Associatioii. 


[392 


RATES  OF  INTEREST  REALIZED  ON  INDIA  BONDS  FOR  PERIODS 
SPECIFIED.! 


Silver. 

. 
J 

Gold. 

i 

Appreciation  of  Gold  in 
Silver. 

Estimated. 
a 

Actual. 

1875-91  .... 

1876-92    .... 

1877-93  .... 
1878-94  .... 
1879-95  .... 

4.1 
4.3 

4-5 
4.6 
4.8 

3-5 
3-6 
3-6 
3.8 
3-9 

.6 

.7 
•9 
.8 
•9 

1.6 
1.8 
2.1 
2.6 
2.4 

Average  .... 

4-5 

3-7 

.8 

2.1 

The  average  estimated  appreciation  for  the  periods 
taken  is  .8%,  which  is  slightly  more  than  one  third  of 
the  average  actual  appreciation,  2.1%.  Perhaps  to  ob- 
tain the  net  estimate  of  investors  as  to  the  fall  of  ex- 
change we  ought  to  deduct  from  the  .8%  another  .\^'/o  due 
to  the  trouble  and  expense  of  obtaining  English  money 
for  Indian  exchange,  for  it  will  be  remembered  that  even 
before  the  fall  of  exchange  began,  the  rates  yielded  to 
investors  differed  by  .2%.^  We  thus  obtain  ,7%  as  the 
extent  to  which,  on  the  average,  investors  protected 
themselves  against  the  fall  in  silver  during  the  period 

'  The  methods  by  which  the  first  columu  is  computed  are  the  same 
as  those  explained  in  the  preceding  chapter,  account  being  taken  of 
the  fact  that  the  price  quotations  for  rupee  paper  are  not  "flat,"  so  that 
no  corrections  for  accrued  interest  need  be  applied.  For  computing 
the  second  column  a  more  laborious  method  was  necessary,  due  to  the 
fact  that  the  quotations  are  not  continuous  for  the  same  bond.  The 
earlier  ones  are  for  a  4  %  bond  and  the  later  for  a  3  %  bond.  The 
buyer  of  a  4  %  bond  is  regarded  as  converting  it  into  the  3  %  at  the 
current  price  in  1888,  the  date  of  maturity  of  the  earlier  bond.  As  no 
bond  tables  apply  to  such  conversions,  tables  of  present  values  were 
used  and  that  rate  was  found  by  trial  (and  interpolation)  which  would 
make  the  present  value  of  all  benefits  equal  to  the  purchase  price. 

^This  probably  included  besides  the  brokerage  and  trouble  of  ob- 
taining and  selling  "  interest  bills  ",  the  risks  even  at  those  early 
dates  of  a  falling  or  fluctuating  exchange. 


393]  Appreciation  and  hiterest.  51 

named.  The  remaining  fall,  1.4%,  implies  a  rela- 
ative  loss  to  the  holders  of  rupee  paper  and  a  gain 
to  the  holders  of  gold  bonds.  Had  the  business 
world  fully  foreseen  the  fall  of  Indian  exchange,  rupee 
paper  would  have  been  cheaper  or  gold  bonds  dearer 
than  they  actually  were,  or  both.  The  rates  of  interest 
realized  in  the  two  standards  during  the  periods  men- 
tioned would  have  been  spread  apart  ( at  most )  i  ^/^  ^ 
further. 

§3. 

The  question  arises  at  this  point,  how  is  this  1)4  fo  to 
be  distributed?  Did  investors  overestimate  silver  or 
underestimate  gold  most  ?  There  is  nothing  in  the  fore- 
going investigation  to  decide  this  vexed  question.  Our 
quantitative  result  is  purely  a  differential  one.  But 
other  sorts  of  evidence  point  strongly  to  the  conclusion 
that  the  major  part  of  the  miscalculation  was  on  the  sil- 
ver side.  So  far  as  "  demonetization  "  is  concerned,  the 
effect  on  silver  must  have  been,  according  to  any  reason- 
able view,  greater  than  the  effect  on  gold,  and  in  conse- 
quence any  unforeseen  part  of  these  effects  would  be 
probably  greater  in  the  case  of  silver  than  in  the  case  of 
gold.  So  far  as  production  is  concerned,  the  disturb- 
ance in  silver  was  far  greater  than  that  in  gold  either 
when  reckoned  absolutely  or  in  proportion  to  the  total 
masses  whose  values  would  be  affected.  Finally,  since 
the  break-down  of  bimetallism  in  1873-4,  the  world-wide 
agitation  to  "  rehabilitate  silver  "  has  held  out  a  delusive 
hope  which  must  have  acted  to  give  the  silver  bonds  a 
higher  price  than  they  "  were  worth."  The  strength  of 
this  agitation  need  scarcely  be  dwelt  on  here.  It  found 
expression  in  many  bills  in  Congress  which  were  never 
passed  and  in  two  which  were  passed,  in  numerous  pro- 


50 


American  Economic  Association. 


[39- 


RATES  OF  INTEREST  REALIZED  ON  INDIA  BONDS  FOR  PERIODS 
SPECIFIED. 1 


Silver. 

Gold. 

Appreciation  of  Gold  in 
Silver. 

Estimated. 

Actual. 

J 

z 

a 

1875-91  .... 

1876-92    .... 

1877-93  •  .  .  . 

4.1 
4.3 
4-5 

3-5 
3-6 
3.6 

.6 

•  7 
•9 

1.6 
1.8 
2.1 

IS78-94  .... 

4.6 

3.8 

.8 

2.6 

1879-95  .... 

4.8 

3-9 

•9 

2.4 

Average  .... 

4-5 

3-7 

.8 

2.1 

The  average  estimate4  appreciation  for  the  periods 
taken  is  .8%,  which  is  slightly  more  than  one  third  of 
the  average  actual  appreciation,  2.1%.  Perhaps  to  ob- 
tain the  net  estimate  of  investors  as  to  the  fall  of  ex- 
change we  ought  to  deduct  from  the  .8%  another  ,  i  %  due 
to  the  trouble  and  expense  of  obtaining  English  money 
for  Indian  exchange,  for  it  will  be  remembered  that  even 
before  the  fall  of  exchange  began,  the  rates  yielded  to 
investors  differed  by  .2%.^  We  thus  obtain  .7%  as  the 
extent  to  which,  on  the  average,  investors  protected 
themselves  against  the  fall  in  silver  during  the  period 

^  The  methods  by  which  the  first  column  is  computed  are  the  same 
as  those  explained  in  the  preceding  chapter,  account  being  taken  of 
the  fact  that  the  price  quotations  for  rupee  paper  are  not  "flat,"  so  that 
no  corrections  for  accrued  interest  need  be  applied.  For  computing 
the  second  column  a  more  laborious  method  was  necessary,  due  to  the 
fact  that  the  quotations  are  not  continuous  for  the  same  bond.  The 
earlier  ones  are  for  a  4  %  bond  and  the  later  for  a  3  %  bond.  The 
buyer  of  a  4  %  bond  is  regarded  as  converting  it  into  the  3  %  at  the 
current  price  in  j8S8,  the  date  of  maturity  of  the  earlier  bond.  As  no 
bond  tables  apply  to  such  conversions,  tables  of  present  values  were 
used  and  that  rate  was  found  b}'  trial  (and  interpolation)  which  would 
make  the  present  value  of  all  benefits  equal  to  the  purchase  price. 

^This  probably  included  besides  the  brokerage  and  trouble  of  ob- 
taining and  selling  "  interest  bills  ",  the  risks  even  at  those  early 
dates  of  a  falling  or  fluctuating  exchange. 


393]  Appreciation  and  Interest.  51 

named.  The  remaining  fall,  1.4%,  implies  a  rela- 
ative  loss  to  the  holders  of  rupee  paper  and  a  gain 
to  the  holders  of  gold  bonds.  Had  the  business 
world  fully  foreseen  the  fall  of  Indian  exchange,  rupee 
paper  would  have  been  cheaper  or  gold  bonds  dearer 
than  they  actually  were,  or  both.  The  rates  of  interest 
realized  in  the  two  standards  during  the  periods  men- 
tioned would  have  been  spread  apart  ( at  most )  i  ^^  ^ 
further. 

§3- 

The  question  arises  at  this  point,  how  is  this  i}4  fo  to 
be  distributed?  Did  investors  overestimate  silver  or 
underestimate  gold  most  ?  There  is  nothing  in  the  fore- 
going investigation  to  decide  this  vexed  question.  Our 
quantitative  result  is  purely  a  differential  one.  But 
other  sorts  of  evidence  point  ^t^ongly  to  the  conclusion 
that  the  major  part  of  the  miscalculation  was  on  the  sil- 
ver side.  So  far  as  "  demonetization  "  is  concerned,  the 
effect  on  silver  must  have  been,  according  to  any  reason- 
able view,  greater  than  the  effect  on  gold,  and  in  conse- 
quence any  unforeseen  part  of  these  effects  would  be 
probably  greater  in  the  case  of  silver  than  in  the  case  of 
gold.  So  far  as  production  is  concerned,  the  disturb- 
ance in  silver  was  far  greater  than  that  in  gold  either 
when  reckoned  absolutely  or  in  proportion  to  the  total 
masses  whose  values  would  be  affected.  Finally,  since 
the  break-down  of  bimetallism  in  1873-4,  the  world-wide 
agitation  to  "  rehabilitate  silver  "  has  held  out  a  delusive 
hope  which  must  have  acted  to  give  the  silver  bonds  a 
higher  price  than  they  "  were  worth."  The  strength  of 
this  agitation  need  scarcely  be  dwelt  on  here.  It  found 
expression  in  many  bills  in  Congress  which  were  never 
passed  and  in  two  which  were  passed,  in  numerous  pro- 


52  American  Economic  Association.  [394 

posals  in  Germany,  in  silver  commissions  there  and  in 
England,  and  in  three  international  conferences.  If  any 
further  evidence  is  needed  that  this  agitation  contrib- 
uted to  mislead  investors  as  to  the  future  of  silver,  it 
can  be  found  by  examining  the  discussions  and  mistaken 
prophecies  on  silver,  contributed  to  the  Economist  and 
other  trade  journals.  It  would  seem  extremely  improb- 
able that  these  hopes  for  the  "  rehabilitation  of  silver  " 
have  acted  to  depress  the  price  of  gold  bonds  rather  than 
to  raise  the  price  of  silver  bonds. 

For  these  reasons  it  seems  likely  that,  of  the  lyi'fo 
relative  gain  or  loss,  not  more  than  half  represents  an 
unexpected  gain  on  the  gold  bonds.  That  is,  the  inter- 
est realized  on  the  gold  bonds,  if  higher  than  it  should 
be,  was  not  higher  by  more  than  Y^'fc  If  this  be  true 
of  one  gold  investment  it  was  undoubtedly  true  of  all 
gold  investments  and  of  the  whole  money  market  in 
London.  This  affords  therefore,  a  probable  upper  limit 
to  the  debtor's  loss  in  England  for  contracts  made  since 
1874.  But  even  if  the  miscalculation  was  twice  as  great 
for  gold  as  for  silver,  the  upper  limit  becomes  only  i  ^. 

Our  result  therefore,  is  that  the  average  debtor's  loss 
in  London  for  contracts  made  since  the  fall  of  silver  be- 
gan, was  probably  less  than  y^  ^  and  almost  certainly 
less  than  i  ^  per  annum.  In  Chapter  X  we  shall  at- 
tempt to  find  a  lower  limit. 


A  great  deal  has  been  written  on  the  loss  incurred  by 
India  in  paying  her  annual  interest  to  England  in  gold, 
but  little  is  said  of  the  interest  paid  at  home  in  silver.  Of 
India's  national  debt,  about  ^100,000,000  are  in  gold 
and  Rx  100,000,000  in  rupees.     This  rupee  debt  was 


395]  Appreciation  and  Interest.  53 

almost  all  in  force  twenty  years  ago  and  was  then  equiva- 
lent to  ^100,000,000,  but  today  it  is  worth  only  ^60,- 
000,000.  The  difference  may  mean  an  added  burden  of 
gold  debt,  but  it  may  also  mean  a  lessened  burden  of 
silver  debt  and  it  is  by  no  means  impossible  that,  so  far 
as  national  indebtedness  is  concerned,  India  is  better  off 
than  she  would,  have  been  if  a  bimetallic  tie  between 
silver  and  gold  had  been  maintained. 

In  this  connection  it  may  be  worth  while  to  point  out 
a  curious  oversight  in  Mr.  Elijah  Helm's  recent  book.^ 
In  Chapter  XVI  he  proposes  the  conversion  of  the  4^ 
rupee  debt  into  a  3^  gold  debt  and,  assuming  very 
plausibly  that  the  gold  bonds  could  be  sold  for  99,  shows 
that  so  long  as  exchange  remained  at  its  present  level, 
there  would  be  an  annual  saving  of  interest  oi  Rs 
160,000.  This  is  correct  enough,  but  he  next  attempts 
to  show  that  if  exchange  should  gradually  fall  there 
would  continue  to  be  a  saving  until  it  should  sink  to 
ioj4d.  This  is  entirely  erroneous.  It  takes  account  only 
of  the  annual  interest  and  not  of  the  deferred  principal 
which  if  in  gold,  grows  progressively  onerous  in  terms 
of  silver.  It  is  odd  that  a  bimetallist  who  portrays  so 
vividly  the  evils  to  the  debtor  from  an  appreciating  gold 
principal  should  have  found  himself  in  the  position  of 
deliberately  advising  a  debtor  to  adopt  that  standard  to 
lessen  his  burden  of  interest.  In  the  same  year  that 
Mr.  Helm's  book  was  written,  the  Indian  Government 
converted  its  4^  rupee  debt,  not  into  gold,  but  into 
another  rupee  debt  at  S}4  fo. 

1  "The  Joint  Standard,"  (London  and  New  York,  1894.) 


CHAPTER  X. 

MONEY   AND    COMMODITIES. 

§1. 

In  attempting  to  apply  our  theory  to  periods  of  rising 
and  falling  prices,  we  are  met  by  the  difficulty  that 
comparison  can  only  be  made  between  successive  periods. 
We  can  learn  what  the  rate  of  interest  has  been  since 
1873,  ^^^  "^^  cannot  know  what  it  would  have  been  if 
bimetallism  had  been  extended  or  if  the  world's  cur- 
rency had  been  so  expanded  as  to  have  prevented  the 
fall  of  prices.  Without  this  missing  term  of  compari- 
son, it  is  difficult  to  measure  the  influence  of  the  pro- 
gressive scarcity  of  gold,  if  such  there  has  been,  upon 
the  rate  of  interest.  It  does  not  answer  the  purpose 
merely  to  compare  the  rates  of  interest  before  and  after 
1873.  No  two  periods  are  so  alike  industrially  that  we 
can  say  they  differ  only  in  the  state  of  the  monetary 
standard.  Other  influences  innumerable  affect  the 
"  value  of  money"  on  the  money  market.  Individual 
quotations  at  different  times  on  the  same  market  vary 
from  one  half  of  one  per  cent,  to  fifty  per  cent,  while 
yearly  averages  vary  from  one  to  seven  per  cent.  We 
can  never  wholly  eliminate  all  causes  but  one,  and  even 
partial  elimination  is  possible  only  by  taking  averages 
for  periods  of  several  years  each.  In  spite  of  these  diffi- 
culties however,  certain  general  conclusions  can  be 
established. 

§2. 

Our  main  problem  is  not  concerned  with  high  and 
low  prices  but  with  rising  or  falling  prices.     But  we 


397] 


Appreciation  and  Interest. 


55 


note  in  passing  an  important  generalization  in  regard  to 
price  levels  and  the  rate  of  interest.  Shall  we  associate 
high  interest  with  high  prices  or  with  low  prices  ?  To 
answer  this  question  the  following  table  is  constructed. 
Two  rates  of  interest  are  given  for  each  decade.     The 

MARKET  RATES  OF  INTEREST  IX  RELATION  TO  HIGH 
AND  LOW  PRICES.i 


1824  to 

:  1831 

;  incl. 

1832  to  1842  to 
1841      1851 
incl.     incl. 

1852  to 

I86I 

incL 

1862  to 
1871 
incl. 

1872  to 
1881 
incl. 

1882  to 
1891 
incl. 

London,     High  prices 
"            Low  prices  . 

13.8 
;    T,  2 

4.4      3-6 
3.2       2.6 

5-4 
3-0 

5-1 

2.6 

3-7 

2.5 

30 
2.5 

New  York,  High  prices    .     . 
"            Low  prices  .... 

9-1 
91 

7.4 
6.7 

7.0 

5-1 

5-3 
5.1 

Berlin,        High  prices 
"            Low  prices  . 

4.6 

3-4 

3-7 

3-2 

3-3 
2.7 

Paris,          High  prices    .     .      . 
"             Low  prices  .... 

i 

4.1 
2.4 

2.6 
2.6 

^  Calcutta,    High  prices 
"            Low  prices  . 

6,2 
5-6 

5-4 
6.2 

'  Tokyo,        High  prices    .     . 
"            Low  prices  .... 

■ 

12.3 
12.0 

lO.I 

10. 1 

*  Shanghai,  High  prices 
"             Low  prices  . 

'            i 

;   6.0 

.   . ; .   . ! .    .  1 .   . 

i    5-7 

^  This  table  is  constructed  from  the  data  given  in  the  Appendix. 
For  New  York,  the  rates  for  the  first  decade  are  averaged  from  the 
column  in  the  Appendix  headed  "60  days,"  and  are  not  to  be  com- 
pared with  those  for  the  remaining  decades,  which  are  averaged  from 
the  column  headed  "  Prime  two  name  60  days."  The  index  numbers 
of  prices  which  have  been  employed  are  those  of  Jevons  (1S24-51) 
and  Sauerbeck  (1S52-91)  for  England,  Soetbeer  and  Heinz  for  Ger- 
many, the  Aldrich  Senate  report  for  the  United  States  and  France, 
and  the  Japanese  report  for  India,  Japan  and  China.  (See  Appendix, 
\  3).  The  table  ends  in  1S91  because  there  are  no  index  numbers  for 
the  United  States  since  that  year. 

2  For  Calcutta  the  rate  for  the  bank  of  Bengal  is  employed,  no 
"market"  rate  being  available.  The  first  column  is  for  1873-81  in- 
stead of  1S72-81,  for  the  reason  that  no  index  number  for  1872  is 
available. 

*  For  Tokyo  the  first  column  is  for  1S73-81  for  the  same  reason. 

*  For  Shanghai  the  period  is  1S85-93  instead  of  1S82-91,  for  the  rea- 
son that  the  available  rates  begin  in  1885  and  the  index  numbers  end 
in  1893. 


56  American  Economic  Associatio7i.  [398 

first,  opposite  "  high  prices,"  is  the  average  rate  for 
those  years  of  the  decade  whose  price  levels,  as  shown 
by  an  index  number,  were  above  the  average  price  level 
for  the  whole  decade  ;  the  second  is  the  average  rate  for 
the  years  whose  prices  were  below  the  general  average. 

Of  the  21  comparisons  contained  in  this  table,  17  show 
higher  rates  for  high-price  years  than  for  low-price 
years,  one  shows  the  opposite  condition  and  three  show 
equal  rates  in  the  two  cases.  As  the  table  covers  68 
years  for  London,  40  for  New  York,  30  for  Berlin,  20 
for  Paris,  19  each  for  Calcutta  and  Tokyo,  and  9  for 
Shanghai,  or  205  years  in  the  aggregate,  the  result 
may  be  accepted  with  great  confidence  that  high  and 
low  prices  are  usually  associated  with  high  and  low 
interest  respectively. 

There  are  two  probable  reasons  for  this  connection. 
One  is  that  high  general  prices  usually  mean  scarcity  of 
capital  rather  than  abundance  of  money,  while  low  prices 
generally  mean  abundance  of  capital,  not  scarcity  of 
money.  This  corresponds  to  the  observations  of  Jevons 
on  the  relation  of  the  rate  of  discount  to  the  price  of 
wheat ;  ^  the  other  reason  is  connected  with  periods  of 
speculation  and  depression  and  will  be  discussed  in  §  12. 

§3. 

The  relation  of  high  or  low  |)rices  to  the  rate  of  inter- 
est must  not  be  confused  with  the  relation  of  rising  or 
falling  prices  to  the  rate  of  interest ",  to  which  vv  e  now 
turn. 

^  "Investigations  in  Currency  and  Finance,"  (1884),  p.  XIV. 

^  de  Haas  appears  to  have  fallen  into  this  confusion  both  in  his  crit- 
icism of  Jevons  and  in  his  treatment  of  statistics.  See  "A  third 
element  in  the  rate  of  interest,"  Journal  of  the  Royal  Statistical 
Society,  March,  1889. 


399]  Appreciation  and  Interest.  57 

It  was  predicted  by  Mr.  Gibbs/  formerly  a  director  of 
the  Bank  of  England,  and  by  other  eminent  bimetallists 
that  the  progressive  scarcity  of  gold  would  raise  the  rate 
of  interest.  Such  a  scarcity  makes  a  stringency  in  the 
money  market,  and  the  banks,  each  struggling  to  attract 
reserves  from  the  others,  will  raise  their  rates.  This 
prophecy,  however,  has  not  been  fulfilled.  Scarcely  had 
Mr.  Gibbs  made  his  prediction  when  the  rate  fell  enor- 
mously. Some  monometallists  have  argued  from  this  fact 
that  there  has  been  no  appreciation  of  gold  ^.  But  the 
theory  that  appreciation  raises  interest  has  been  confi- 
dently afiirmed  on  both  sides  and  has  even  received  the 
stamp  of  approval  of  Mr.  Giffen.^     It  is,  however,  utterly 

'  "The  Bimetallic  Controversy,"  (London,  18S6),  pp.  19,  231,  245-8-9, 

373- 

2 Report  of  the  Gold  and  Silver  Commission,  (1888),  p.  120;  also 
Professor  Laughlin  in  Quarterly  Journal  of  Economics,  Vol.  i.,  p.  344. 

3  "  Essays  in  Finance,"  (2d  series,  1886),  p.  70.  "  The  years  oi  fall- 
ing prices  and  rising  prices  also  correspond  as  a  rule  with  those  years 
in  which  high  rates  and  low  reserves,  and  low  rates  and  high  reserves 
are  combined."  This  (so  far  as  prices  and  interest  are  concerned)  is 
not  only  the  exact  opposite  of  the  truth  but  it  is  flatly  contradicted  by 
the  few  figures  which  Mr.  Giflfen  himself  brings  forward.  Of  these 
he  says  :  "  .  .  in  years  like  1865  and  1866  with  which  the  Table 
begins,  there  is  an  obvious  connection  between  the  low  reserve  and 
high  rate  of  discount  of  those  years  and  the  high  Index  No.,  leading 
in  the  following  [!]  years  1867-71  to  a  simultaneous  fall  in  the  Index 
No.  and  the  rates  of  discount  .  .  "  He  adds  :  "  .  .  the  low 
prices  rather  succeed  the  high  discount  rates  than  exactly  correspond 
.  .  "  Coming  to  the  recent  period  of  gold  contraction,  he  says  : 
"  Turning  to  the  rate  of  discount,  we  find  the  facts  once  more  in  cor- 
respondence. What  we  find  first  is  a  striking  disturbance  of  the 
money  market  at  the  maximum  period  of  high  prices,  1871-73  [a  pe- 
riod of  rising  prices  and  high  interest],  when  the  contraction  of  gold 
begins."  Of  the  period  1875-79  (falling  prices  and  low  interest),  he 
writes:  "With  a  minimum  average  monthly  rate  of  2  per  cent  in 
each  year,  the  following  maximum  monthly  rates  were  nevertheless 
touched,  viz"  :  [4^,  4f,  4f,  sf,  4^  %s].  "In  the  present  year  (1885) 
when  with  dull  trade  and  low  prices  the  reserve  should  be  full  and 
discount  rates  low,  we  find  that  with  a  minimum  of  2  per  cent,  there 
is  again  to  be  a  comparatively  high  maximum  (4  %)  within  the  year." 


58  American  Ecoyiornic  Associatio7i.  [400 

at  variance  with  facts.  Tliat  an  abnormally  high  or  low 
bank  reserve  is  correlated  with  low  and  high  interest  is 
abnndantly  justified  in  theory  and  verified  in  practice.' 
But  the  normal  bank  reserve  itself  shrinks  with  a 
shrinkage  of  gold  and  in  consequence  the  inference  that  a 
contraction  of  the  general  gold  supply  will  raise  interest 
is  fallacious.^ 

When  prices  are  rising  or  falling,  money  is  depreciat- 
ing or  appreciating  relatively  to  commodities.  Our 
theory  would  therefore  require  high  or  low  interest  ac- 
cording as  prices  are  rising  or  falling,  provided  we  as- 
sume that  the  rate  of  interest  in  the  commodity  stand- 
ard should  not  vary.  This  assumption  would  be  thor- 
oughly justified  only  in  case  the  two  periods  were  eco- 
nomically alike  in  all  respects  except  in  the  expansion 
or  contraction  of  credit  and  currency.     In  the  following 

"To  sum  up — what  I  have  to  say  of  the  recent  discount  rates  is  that 
while  there  has  been  an  undoubted  fall  in  recent  years,  corresponding 
to  the  abundance  of  capital,  yet  the  market  has  been  fevered  by  the 
demands  on  the  reserve  .  .  "  "The  monetary  history  of  recent 
years  has  accordingly  been  very  like  what  was  to  be  expected  on  the 
theory  above  set  forth,  assuming  a  contraction  of  gold  to  have  oc- 
curred, .  .  finally  the  money  market  has  been  irritable  and  fever- 
ish in  a  remarkable  manner  during  the  period  of  contraction."  Thus, 
beginning  with  a  statement  that  years  of  falling  and  rising  prices  cor- 
respond to  years  of  high  and  low  interest,  Mr.  Giffen  cites  facts  which 
show  that  the  opposite  is  true,  but  proceeds  complacently  to  compare 
the  rates  of  periods  of  rising  (or  falling)  prices  with  the  prices  of  the 
succeeding  period  of  falling  (or  rising)  prices.  As  the  period  of  fall- 
ing prices  in  which  he  writes  is  unfinished,  he  can  onl}-  say  of  it  that 
the  "money  market  has  been  irritable  and  feverish  in  a  remarkable 
manner."  Another  monometallist,  Clarmont  Daniell,  objects  to  bi- 
metallism for  India  on  the  ground  that  it  would  deplete  India  of  silver 
and  raise  the  rate  of  interest.  (  "The  Bimetallic  Controversy,"  p.  257). 
On  this  point  see  \  5. 

^See,  ^.  ^.,  Giffen's  "Essays,"  ibid.,  or  the  diagrams  in  Clare's 
"  Money-Market  Primer,"  L,ondon,  1891  ;  also  F.  M.  Taylor,  "Do  we 
want  an  Elastic  Currency,"  Political  Science  Quarterly,  March,  1S96, 
pp.  133-157- 

^  See,  however,  §  12,  note. 


40i] 


Appreciation  and  Interest. 


59 


table  for  London  the  periods  are  selected  to  correspond 
with  the  main  movements  of  prices.  Thus  the  period 
1826-29  was  a  period  of  falling  prices  so  that  money  ap- 
preciated in  terms  of  commodities  at  the  average  rate  of 
\.2fo  per  annum.  This  is  indicated  in  the  third  column 
by  the  figure  +4.2.  In  the  period  1836-39  prices  rose 
so  that  money  fell  at  the  rate  of  2.3^  per  annum,  indi- 
cated by  — 2.3. 

I^ONDON  RATES  OF  INTEREST  IN  REIyATlON  TO  RISING 
AND  FAI,I,ING  PRICES.i 


Appreciation  of 

virtual  Interest 

Bank. 

Market. 
i 

Money  in 
Commodities, 

a 

m 
Commodities. 

(Market.) 
J 

1826 — 29    •   • 

4.4 

3-5 

4-4.2 

7.8 

1830—35 

4.0 

3-2 

0.0 

3-2 

1836—39 

4-7 

4.2 

—2.3 

1.8 

1840—44 

4.2 

3-5 

+5.9 

9.6 

1845—47 

3-7 

4.2 

— 3-0 

I.I 

1848—52 

2.9 

2-5 

+  1.2 

37 

1853—57 

4.1 

5-3 

—2.4 

2.8 

1858—64 

4.4 

4.2 

— 3-0 

I.I 

1865—70 

3-8 

3.6 

+  1.1 

4-7 

1871—73 

3-9 

3-7 

—6.2 

—2.7 

1874—79 

3.2 

2.7 

-f4-3 

7-1 

1880—87 

3-3 

2.6 

+3-8 

6.5 

1888—90 

3-8 

2.9 

—1.4 

1-5 

1891—95 

2.6 

1.6 

+3.8 

5-5 

Mean  Variation, 

•5 

■  7 

2.6 

^  This  table  is  constructed  from  the  data  in  the  Appendix.  The 
third  column  is  based  on  index  numbers,  (Jevons'  for  1826-52,  and 
Sauerbeck's  for  the  remaining  years).  The  index  numbers  for  two 
dates,  as  1826  and  1829,  being  given,  their  inverse  ratio  gives  the  rela- 
tive value  of  money  (in  commodities),  at  those  two  dates.  From  these 
it  is  easy  to  calculate  the  average  annual  change  in  its  value.  Theo- 
retically, since  the  loans  here  included  run  usually,  perhaps  30  to  90 
days,  the  quotations  averaged  should  begin  at  the  first  of  the  two  dates, 
and  cease,  say,  60  days  before  the  second.  But  the  index  numbers  are 
not  always  for  definite  points  of  time,  nor  can  the  interest  quotations 
be  subjected  to  such  minute  corrections  without  an  immense  expendi- 
ture of  labor.  Hence,  the  method  adopted  has  been  to  average  the 
rates  for  all  the  years  of  a  period,  e.g.,  for  the  four  years,  1S26-29, 
while  the  "appreciation"  is  reckoned  between  those  dates,  and 
thus  is  an  average  for  only  three  years.     If  the  index  numbers  repre- 


6o  American  Economic  Association.  [402 

If  this  table  be  exaiiiiiied  in  successive  periods,  it  will 
be  found,  in  eleven  out  of  thirteen  sequences  for  bank 
rates  and  in  ten  out  of  thirteen  for  market  rates,  that  in- 
terest is  high  or  low  according  to  the  degree  in  which 
prices  are  rising  or  falling.  Attention  is  called  particu- 
larly to  the  period  1S53-57  during  which  prices  rose 
very  fast  simultaneously  with  and  presumably  because 
of  the  great  gold  production.  The  market  rate  of  in- 
terest averaged  5.3/^  which  was  far  higher,  not  only 
than  in  any  subsequent,  but  also  than  in  any  previous 
period,  although  it  can  scarcely  be  supposed  that  capital 
was  less  abundant  This  fact  has  been  commented  upon 
by  various  writers,  ^  and  is  usually  attributed  to  trade  ac- 
tivity and  speculation.  Such  a  reason,  however,  is  not 
really  explanatory  unless  the  reason  for  the  speculation 
is  also  given. 

The  theory  here  offerred,  that  the  high  rate  represent- 
ed an  effort  to  offset  the  depreciation  of  money,  not  only 
affords  a  complete  explanation  but  in  connection  with 
another  fact  soon  to  be  noted,  explains  the  trade  activ- 
ity also. 

§4- 

The  following  table  for  Berlin  displays  the  same  con- 
nection between  price  movements  and  interest. 

sent  the  price  levels  at  the  middle  of  1826  and  of  1829,  then  the  average 
interest  rates  ought  in  theory  to  include  only  the  last  six  months  of 
1826,  and  the  first  four  months  of  1829.  But  it  seems  better  to  include 
too  much  at  both  ends,  than  to  omit  the  averages  for  1826  and  1829 
altogether,  for  the  reason  that  an  average  is  the  more  valuable  the 
greater  the  number  of  terms  included.  The  method  adopted  also 
seems  better  than  omitting  either  otie  of  the  extreme  years,  partly  for 
the  reason  just  given,  and  partly  because  both  years  usually  belong 
to  the  same  economic  movement. 

^  E.g.,  Sir  Louis  Mallet.  Note  to  Report  of  Gold  and  Silver  Com- 
mission, ( 1888)  p.  120;  andjevons'  "  Investigations  in  Currency  and 
Finance,"  (1884)  p.  95.     The  latter  will  be  again  referred  to. 


403] 


Appreciation  and  Interest. 


61 


BERLIN  RATES  OF  INTEREST  IN  REI.ATION  TO  RISING 
AND  FALLING  PRICES.  1 


Bank. 


Market 


Apprecia- 
tion of 
Money  in 
Commod- 
ities. 
a 


Virtural 
Interest  in 
Commod- 
ities. 
(Bank.) 
h 


Virtual 
Interest  in 
Commod- 
ities. 
(Market.) 

J2 


1851-52 

1853-57  ■ 

1858-64, 

1865-70 

1871-73 

1874-79 

1880-83 

1884-88 

1889-91 

1892-95 


4.0 
4-7 
4-3 
4-7 
4-5 
4-3 
43 
3-6 
4.0 
3-4 


3-7' 

4.0 

4.1 

3-2 

3-4 

2.5 

3-1 

2.2 


-1-5 

-3-3 

— 2.2 

0.0 

-4  I 

+3.I 
—0.1 
+2.9 
—1.4 
+5-2 


2.4 
1.2 
2.0 


1.4 
4.0 
—0.2 
6.4 
3-3 
5-5 
1-7 
7-5 


Mean  variation,  1858-91 


•  4 


2.1 


In  the  foregoing  table  the  relation  is  observed  in  six 
out  of  nine  sequences  for  bank  rates  (one  being  neutral) 
and  in  six  out  of  seven  for  market  rates. 

For  France,  index  numbers  covering  a  wide  range  of 
articles  are  not  available.  Using  those  given  in  the  Al- 
drich  report  for  sixteen  articles,  we  have  : 

PARIS  RATES  OF  INTEREST  IN  RELATION  TO    RISING 
AND    FALLING  PRICES. 2 


1861-64. 
1865-70 . 
1871-73. 

1874-79  . 
1880-86. 
1887-90. 
1891-95  , 


Bank. 


5-1 
3-2 
5-3 
3-1 
3-2 

3-1 
2.6 


46^ 

2.6 

2.8 
2.6 
2.0 


Appreciation  in 
Commodities. 


+  3-6 

-  4.5 
+  43 
+  2.3 

—  5-1 


1  This  table  is  constructed  from  the  data  in  the  Appendix.  The 
average  in  the  second  column,  marked  (i),  is  for  the  years  1861-64, 
not  1858-64.  The  "appreciation"  is  calculated  from  the  figures  of 
Soetbeer  and  Heinz,  as  given  in  the  Aldrich  report. 

2  This  table  is  constructed  from  the  data  in  the  Appendix.  The 
average  in  the  second  column  marked  (2)  is  for  the  years  1872-73,  not 
1871-73. 


62 


A?}!C7'ica?i  Economic  Association. 


[404 


Here  the  law  is  observed  in  five  out  of  six  sequences 
for  bank  rates  and  three  out  of  four  for  market  rates/ 

It  will  be  noted  that  the  course  of  prices  and  interest 
has  been  very  similar  in  England,  Germany  and  France. 

For  New  York  we  have  the  following  table  : 

NEW    YORK    RATES    OF   INTEREST   IN    RELATION  TO  RISING  AND 
FAI^IvING  PRICES  AND  WAGES.2 


0  i 

0-° 

I.S 

in 

1-1     — 

0] 

g-0 

a  C-I3 

0  ^ 

ii'-S" 

i!^? 

OJ      ,U! 

ii..  (J 

60 

gv§ 

•■3  >.2 

rt  0 

CO:? 

.9  2  a 

•i^.§i^' 

s  0  a 

Call. 

days 

<    u 

s  a  0 

15^ 

3'-'— 

t 

I 

a 

a 

J 

-7 

> 

y 

1849-57  •  . 

6.2 

9.2 

-3-8 

-I.I 

5-1 

8.0 

1858-60  .  . 

5.0 

7-4 

+b.4 

—  I.O 

14-3 

b-z 

1861-65  .  . 

5-9 

8.4 

6.8 

—20.2 

-9-3 

-13-5 

—  I4.S 

-1.7 

—3-1 

1866-74  .  . 

5-4 

8.4 

7-5 

-h4.7 

-05 

13-5 

12.6 

7-9 

7.0 

1875-79  •  • 

.    . 

5-1 

+7.9 

4-3-2 

13-4 

85 

1880-84  •  • 

5-4 

+0.6 

—2.0 

6.0 

3-3 

1885-91  .  . 

5-1 

— 0  2 

-1-3 

4-9 

3-7 

1892-95  .  . 

4.6 

. 

Mean  varia- 

tion, '66-91 

.6 

3-8 

2.1 

We  find  here  the  same  association  of  appreciation  and 
interest  in  all  of  the  three  sequences  for  call  loans,  in 
two  of  the  three  cases  for  60  days  paper  (the  third  being 
neutral)  and  in  three  of  the  five  cases  for  "  prime  "  paper.^ 
This  is  with  reference  to  commodities.  The  same  holds 
true  in  reference  to  wages.  We  find  in  the  successive 
periods  that  interest  is  high  or  low  according  to  the  degree 
in  which  wages  rise  or  fall.  This  is  true  in  each  of  the 
three  sequences  for  call  loans,  in  two  of  the  three  for  60 
days  paper  and  in  three  of  the  four,  for  "  prime  "  paper. 

^Assuming  that  prices  fell,  1891-95. 

'^  This  table  is  constructed  from  the  data  in  the  Appendix.  The 
rates  of  appreciation  are  calculated  from  Falkner's  figures  for  prices 
and  wages  in  the  Aldrich  Report. 

3  Assuming  that  prices  fell,  1892-95. 


405]  Appreciatio7i  and  Interest.  63 

Perhaps  the  most  remarkable  fact  in  this  table  is 
the  extremely  low  rate  for  1875-79.  '^he  average 
is  5. 1  /^  which  is  the  next  but  lowest  in  the  table, 
the  lowest  being  4.6%  for  1892-95.  The  extra- 
ordinary change  in  interest  rates  beginning  in  1875 
has  been  observed  before ;  but  its  connection  with  the 
resumption  act  (as  it  seems  to  the  writer)  has  been  mis- 
construed, Thus  William  Brough  referring  to  that  act 
says  :  ^  "  The  mere  announcement  of  our  intention  to 
put  our  money  on  a  sound  metallic  basis  had  brought 
capital  to  us  in  such  abundance  that  the  resumption  was 
not  only  made  easy,  but  the  normal  rate  of  interest  was 
reduced.  .  .  .  This  remarkable  reduction  .  .  is  ex- 
plainable only  on  the  ground  of  a  large  influx  of  foreign 
capital."  But  this  explanation  would  naturally  require 
a  still  lower  rate  of  interest  after  resumption  had  been 
accomplished.  As  the  facts  are  the  opposite,  there 
seems  little  room  for  doubt  that  the  rate  of  interest  was 
simply  accommodating  itself  in  some  degree  to  the  rapid 
appreciation  involved  in  a  return  to  specie  payments. 

§5- 

The  preceding  statistics  apply  to  gold  standard 
countries.  Index  numbers  for  silver  standard  countries 
are  not  available  prior  to  1873.  It  is,  however,  a  priori 
probable  that  the  relative  price  movements  in  gold  and 
silver  standard  countries  before  and  after  the  rupture  of 
the  bimetallic  tie  in  1874  presented  a  strong  antithesis. 
This  event  marked  a  change  in  gold  standard  countries 
from  rising  to  falling  prices,  while  in  silver  standard 
countries  prices  began  to  rise.  Unless,  therefore,  prices 
in  silver  countries  had  been  rising  previous  to  1874,  and 

1  "  Natural  Law  of  Mouey,"  (New  York,  1894),  p.  124. 


64 


American  Economic  Associatio7i. 


[406 


rising  very  fast  indeed,  the  antithesis  referred  to  must 
have  existed.  It  is,  consequently,  of  much  interest  to 
inquire  whether  the  fall  in  the  rate  of  interest  which 
was  so  marked  for  gold  countries  was  shared  in  equal 
degree  by  silver  countries.  The  following  table  for 
periods  of  five  years  before  and  after  the  silver  and  gold 
standards  began  to  diverge,  throws  some  light  on  this 
problem. 

AVERAGE  BANK  RATES  IN  GOI^D  AND  SILVER  STANDARD  COUNTRIES 
BEFORE  AND  AFTER  THE  BREAKDOWN  OF  BIMETAI^USM.! 


^ 

Tl 

W  u) 

0 

u^ 

0 

iH  tn 

a 

""  t! 

a 

3 
0 

0 

a 

a 
0 

.9" 

_«■ 

0 

lU  3 
MO 

11  i! 

^5 

0 

fi, 

0 

u 

cd 

>  u 

tJ 

fi 

m 

hT 

m 

&< 

% 

<  -^ 

< 

1870-74.  . 

5-1 

16.4 

10.6 

3-7 

4-5 

4.9 

7-5 

10.7 

5-2 

1875-79-  • 

b.5 

14.6 

9.2 

3-0 

4.2 

2.9 

5-1 

10. 1 

3-y 

While  the  results  are  not  conclusive,  they  go  to  con- 
firm our  theory.  In  all  gold  countries  the  rate  fell 
after  the  par  of  exchange  with  silver  countries  was 
broken,  while  in  India  it  rose,  and  this  in  spite  of  the 
flow  of  capital  to  India  from  England  and  other  gold 
countries.  It  is  true  that  in  Japan  and  China  the  rates 
fell.  But  this  fall  was  much  less  than  in  the  gold 
countries,  whereas  we  should  expect  it  to  be  much  greater 
if  the  only  influence  at  work  were  the  migration  of 

^Tbis  table  is  constructed  from  the  data  given  in  the  Appendix. 
Bank  rates  are  selected  rather  than  market  rates,  as  the  latter  are  not 
available  for  Calcutta  and  Shanghai.  For  New  York,  however,  the 
rates  for  "  prime  two  name  60  days  paper  "  are  employed.  Although 
the  United  States  and  Japan  were  on  a  paper  basis  at  the  periods 
given,  the  premium  on  gold  in  the  one  case  and  silver  in  the  other 
moved  in  opposite  directions,  affording,  therefore,  as  great  or  greater 
antithesis  than  if  the  standards  had  been  simply  gold  and  silver.  For 
the  American  premium  see  Chapter  VIII,  §  2  ;  for  the  Japanese,  see 
Appendix,  \  3,  note. 


407] 


Appreciation  and  Interest. 


65 


capital.  Such  extraordinary  rates  as  ruled  in  China  and 
Japan  in  the  '70's  must  have  been  extremely  sensitive  to 
the  influence  of  an  influx  of  capital.  Even  though 
British  investment  in  Japan  or  China  may  have  been 
much  less  than  in  India,  we  should  expect  its  tendency 
to  reduce  the  native  rate  of  interest  to  be  more  effective 
where  that  rate  was  10^  or  15  ^  than  where  it  was  5  ^. 
An  added  reason  for  a  fall  in  rates  in  Shanghai  and 
Tokyo  is  the  narrowness  of  the  areas  affected  by  foreign 
capital,  which,  having  little  opportunity  to  penetrate 
inland,  tends  to  glut  the  market  in  the  open  ports. 

Turning  to  the  period  for  which  index  numbers  are 
available,  we  have  the  following  table  for  India,  Japan 
and  China. 

RATBS  OF  INT:EREST  IN  R^I/ATION  TO  RISING  AND  FAI^LING  PRICES 
IN  CAI,CUTTA,  TOKYO  AND  SHANGHAI.i 


Bank. 

Market. 

Appreciation  in 
Commodities. 

Calcutta  .... 

1873-75 
1876-78 
1879-85 
1886-89 
1890-93 

5-3 
6.8 

5-9 
6.0 

4-3 

+2.6 
—  II.O 

+3-8 
-2.6 

-4-7 

Tokyo  

1873-77 
1878-81 
1882-86 
1887-93 

14.0 
16.3 
12.8 

9-3 

12.0 
12.2 
10.3 

9-4 

—0.2 
-13-3 
+10.4 

-2.8 

Shanghai.  .   .    . 

1874-81 
1882-88 
1889-93 

91 

7-5 
7.0 

5.8^ 
5-8 

-1-4 
+1.3 
-0.9 

Here  we  find   our  theory  confirmed  in  three  out  of 

four  cases  for  India,  two  out  of  three  for  bank  rates  in 

Japan,  and  two  out  of  three  for  market  rates,  one  out  of 

two    for  bank  rates  in  China,  while  the  one  case  for 

market  rates  is  neutral. 

'This  table  is  constructed  from  the  data  given  in  the  Appendix. 
The  entry  marked  (i)  is  for  1885-88,  not  1882-88. 


66  American  Economic  Association.  [408 

Summarizing  the  cases  for  the  seven  countries  exam- 
ined, we  find  57  favorable,  and  16  unfavorable,  to  our 
theory,  distributed  as  follows  : 


Eng- 
land. 

Ger- 
many. 

France. 

United 
.States. 

India. 

Japan. 

China. 

Total 

Favorable  .    . 

21 

12 

8 

8 

3 

4 

I 

57 

Unfavorable  . 

5 

3 

2 

2 

I 

2 

I 

16 

We  therefore  conclude  with  great  confidence  that, 
"  other  things  being  equal,"  the  rate  of  interest  is  high 
when  prices  are  rising  and  low  when  prices  are  falling. 


We  turn  next  to  the  question  hozv  far  the  rate  of  in- 
terest has  been  adjusted  to  price  movements.  The  for- 
mula (1  + /)=(!  + 2  )(i  +'^)  or  its  more  convenient 
form  for  present  purposes,  /  ^  /  +  «  +  ia.,  enables  us  to 
calculate  the  rate  of  interest  in  the  commodity  standard 
which  was  equivalent  to  the  money  interest  paid  in  each 
period.  Thus  in  London  for  1826-29  the  rate  of  inter- 
est (  z )  in  money  was  3.5  %,  but  money  was  appreciating 
relatively  to  commodities  4.2  ^  (  «  ),  so  that  the  interest 
actually  paid  in  terms  of  commodities  (z.  ^.,  the  forty 
commodities  averaged  by  Jevons)  was  /  =  .035  +  .042 
+  .035  X  .042  =  7.8^.  It  will  be  seen  from  the  table 
in  §  3  that  the  virtual  rate  of  interest  paid  in  commod- 
ities usually  varies  inversely  with  the  rate  paid  in  money. 
For  1853-57,  money  interest  was  5.3%  and  for  1891-95, 
1.6^  but  commodity  interest  for  1853-57  was  2.8^  and 
for  1891-95,  5.5^.  Moreover  commodity  interest  fluc- 
tuated much  more  than  money  interest,  the  mean  varia- 
tion from  the  average  being  for  money  interest  .7  ^,  and 
for  commodity  interest,  2.6^.  All  these  facts  suggest, 
— indeed  practically  demonstrate — that  money  interest 
was  not  adequately  adjusted.     It  is   of  course  not  to  be 


409]  Appreciation  arid  Interest.  67 

assumed  that  commodity  interest  ought  to  be  invariable, 
but  we  can  be  practically  certain  that  its  variations  ought 
not  to  be  three  and  a  half  times  the  variations  in  money 
interest.  Such  fluctuations  must  mean  that  the  price 
movements  were  inadequately  predicted.  If  any  doubts 
were  possible  on  this  point  they  must  disappear  when 
we  find  that  for  1871-73  commodity  interest  was  minus 
2.7^.  Money  lenders  would  have  been  better  off  had 
they  simply  bought  commodities  in  1871  and  held  them 
till  1873.  Such  losses  are  especially  apt  to  appear  in 
short  periods.  Thus  if  we  take  the  period  1824-25,  we 
find  that  the  market  rate  was  Z-l%i  ^^^  '^^te  of  appreci- 
ation was  minus  14.5%  and  the  virtual  rate  of  interest 
in  commodities  minus  11. 2,%. 

The  same  observations  apply  to  the  rates  at  Berlin, 
Paris,  New  York,  Calcutta,  Tokyo  and  Shanghai.  In 
New  York  during  the  inflation  period  1861-65,  com- 
modity interest  sank  to  the  fabulously  low  figure  of  -14.8 
fo ,  though  the  rate  of  interest  in  the  labor  standard  was 
only  -3. 1  fo .  This  shows  in  a  striking  way  how  thor- 
oughly the  greenback  inflation  upset  all  business  cal- 
culations. This  fact  has  generally  been  recognized, 
though  probably  underestimated.  It  is  amply  confirmed 
by  examining  the  predictions  as  to  the  termination  of 
the  war  and  the  reduction  of  the  gold  premium  which 
were  recorded  from  month  to  month  in  the  "  Notes  on 
the  Money  Market "  in  the  ( New  York )  Banker's  Maga- 
zine. In  all  probability  this  is  always  true  of  pe- 
riods of  paper  money  inflation.  Our  tables  show  it  for 
the  Japanese  inflation  of  1878-81. 

§7 

We  can  now  understand  why  a  high  rate  of  interest 
need  not  retard  trade  nor  a  low  rate  stimulate  it.    These 


68  American  Economic  Association.  [410 

facts  have  puzzled  many  writers.  For  instance,'  "  Public 
inquiry  has  been  of  late  strongly  directed  to  the  reasons 
for  the  very  low  rate  of  interest  upon  loanable  capital 
in  the  year  1875,  the  more  especially  as  ten  years  ago 
the  very  high  rates  then  prevailing  created  equal  sur- 
prise. "  Again,^  "  The  effect  of  such  and  many  more 
changes  effected  during  the  last  twenty  years  or  so,  is 
seen  in  a  general  increase  in  wealth  and  of  mercantile 
industry  and  profits.  Thus  only  can  be  explained  the 
extraordinary  high  rate  at  which  the  interest  of  money 
has  in  the  last  ten  years  often  stood.  During  1854-57 
the  rate  of  interest  was  only  for  a  few  months  below 
5  fc ,  but  for  many  months  above  it.  For  more  than  half 
a  year  it  stood  at  6  and  7^,  and  in  the  end  of  1857  it 
remained  for  nearly  two  months  at  \o%.  Again,  in 
1861,  interest  rose  to  6  and  8^,  and  all  this,  to  the  S2ir- 
prise  of  the  elder  generation.^  without  the  general  stop- 
page of  trade.,  the  breach  of  credit.,  and  the  flood  of 
bankruptcy.,  which  has  hitherto  attended  such  rates  of  in- 
terest. It  is  certainly  not  to  increasing  scarcity  of  cap- 
ital we  should  attribute  such  rates,  but  rather  to  a  greatly 
extended  field  for  its  profitable  employment.  "  ^  But 
were  these  rates  high  ?  If  we  turn  to  our  table  for  Lon- 
don rates  we  find  that  the  average  market  rate  for 
1853-57  ^o^s  appear  to  be  the  highest  in  the  table  but, 
unmasking  it  of  the  money  element,  we  find  it  is 
equivalent  to  a  commodity  interest  of  2.8^.  This  is 
i.o^  lower  than  the  average  for  the  whole  period,  1826 
-95.  Should  we  be  surprised  that  industry  did  not  lan- 
guish ? 

'Robert  Baxter,  Journal  of  the  Royal  Statistical  Society,  June,  1S76. 

'^Jevons,    "  Investigations,  "   p.    95.      The  italics   are  the  present 
writer's. 

^This  view  had  also  been  expressed  by  TookeandNewmarch,  "  His- 
tory of  Prices  ",  Vol.  V,  p.  345. 


41 1]  Appreciation  and  Inte^'est.  69 

Professor  Bonamy  Price^  writing  at  a  time  of  very  low 
interest  rates  says  :  "  Everyone  remembers  the  agitations 
associated  with  7^,  the  trepidation  of  merchants,  the 
apprehension  of  losses  in  business.  ...  If  only  a 
moderate  rate  could  be  reckoned  on  as  steady,  how  happy 
would  everyone  have  been  !  .  .  .  Yet  what  are  the  facts 
and  feelings  today?  Is  every  merchant,  every  manu- 
facturer rejoicing  in  the  pleasant  terms  on  which  he  ob- 
tains the  accommodation  so  necessary  for  his  business  ? 
.  .  .  Alas !  no  such  sounds  meet  our  ears.  .  .  .  Com- 
mercial depression  is  the  universal  cry,  depression  prob- 
ably unprecedented  in  duration  in  the  annals  of  trade, 
except  under  the  disturbing  action  of  a  prolonged  war. 
In  the  export  figures,  the  writer  still  fails  to  see 
any  signs  of  the  long-looked-for  revival  of  trade.  Both 
quantities  and  values  continue  to  shrink  in  all  save  a  few 
cases.  .  .  .  What  then  is  the  cause  ?  The  explajta- 
ation  will  certainly  not  be  found  in  gold  nor  in  any  form 
of  currency  whatever.  .  .  .  nor  has  anyoize  said 
anything  so  ridiculous.  .  .  .  That  cause  is  one  and 
one  only  :  over  spending.  " 

If  we  turn  back  to  our  London  table  we  find,  however, 
that  for  1874-79  the  commodity  rate  of  interest  was 
7. 1  %  !  It  would  be  astonishing  if  trade  did  not  shrink 
under  such  a  burden. 

All  these  writers  mistook  high  or  low  nominal  inter- 
est for  high  or  low  real  interest.  Tooke  apparently  did 
the  same.  In  his  "  History  of  Prices  ",  vol.  ii,  p.  349, 
he  names  as  the  last  of  six  reasons  for  the  fall  of  prices 
for  1814-37,  "a  reduction  in  the  general  rate  of  inter- 
est. "  This  is  probabl}^  not  only  an  inversion  of  cause 
and  effect,  but  also,   when  the  veil  of  money  is  thrown 

1"  One  per  cent  ",  Contemporary  Review,  April,  1877.  The  italics 
are  the  present  -writer's. 


70 


American  Economic  Association. 


[412 


off,  a  mis-statement  of  fact.  The  commodity  interest  for 
1826-29  was  7.8%.  It  Avould  seem  that  Tooke,  Price, 
and  Jevons  all  overlooked  the  fact  that  interest,  unlike 
prices,  is  not  an  instantaneous  but  essentially  a  time  phe- 
nomenon. 

§8. 

In  order  to  make  our  results  as  certain  as  possible,  the 
following  table  is  formed  in  which  the  longer  price 
movements  are  selected.  It  consists  of  three  periods,  of 
ten,  twelve,  and  twenty-one  years  respectively. 

LONDOISr  MARKET  RATES  OF  INTEREST  IN  REI^ATION  TO  RISING 
ANT)  FALLING  PRICES,  WAGES,  AND  INCOMES.i 


Market 

interest. 

i 

Apprecia- 
tion of 
Money  in 
Commod- 
ities. 
a 

Virtual 
interest 

in 
commod- 
ities. 
/ 

Apprecia- 
tion of 

Money  in 
Labor. 

a 

Apprecia- 
tion of 
Money  in 
Income. 

a 

Virtual 
interest 

in 
Labor. 

y 

Virtual 
interest 

in 
Income. 

J 

1826-35 
1853-64 
1874-95 

3-4 
4.6 
2.4 

+  1.2 
-0.9 

-1-2.4 

4.6 
3-7 
4-9 

1860-74 

1874-91 

4.0 
2.7 

—  2.1 
0.0 

-2.5 
—0.2 

1.8 
2.7 

1.4 
2.5 

In  averages  covering  so  many  years,  we  may  be  sure 
that  accidental  causes  are  almost  wholly  eliminated. 
We  find  that  during  the  period  of  rising  prices,  1853-64, 
the  average  rate  of  interest  was  2.2^  above  the  average 
for  the  subsequent  period  of  falling  prices,  1874-95,  and 
1.2^  higher  than  in  the  former  period  of  falling  prices, 
1826-35.  The  rates  in  the  commodity  standard  how- 
ever vary  in  the  inverse  order,  the  highest  interest  being 
for  1874-95  and  the  lowest  for  1853-64.  It  is  a  note- 
worthy fact,  in  strong  contrast  with  what  we  have  found 

'  The  rates  of  appreciations  in  labor  and  income  are  based  on 
"  Changes  in  average  wages  in  the  United  Kingdom  between  i860 
and  1 89 1,"  by  A.  L,.  Bowley,  in  the  Journal  of  the  Royal  Statistical 
Society,  June,  1895. 


413]  Appreciatio7i  and  Interest.  71 

true  of  sliort  periods,  that  the  commodity  interest  in  this 
table  of  long  periods  is  less  variable^  than  the  money 
interest.  Thus  the  adjustment  of  (money)  interest  to 
long  price  movements  is  more  perfect  than  to  short. 

§9. 

The  foregoing  table  shows  exactly  how  the  English 
borrower  has  fared  so  far  as  commodities  and  labor  are  con- 
cerned. During  1853-64  he  paid  2^-1%  in  commodities 
but  during  1874-95  he  had  to  pay  4.9%,  an  increase  of 
1.2%.  In  the  labor  standard,  during  1860-74,  he  paid 
1.8%,  and  during  1874-91,  2.7%,  showing  an  increase  of 
.9%,  while  in  the  income  standard  the  rates  were  1.4%, 
and  2.5%  respectively,  showing  an  increase  of  1.1%. 
Now  it  is  quite  conceivable  that  commodity  interest 
should  normally  be  high  during  the  latter  period,  if  this 
period  can  be  shown  to  be  one  of  unusually  rapid 
economic  progress.^     That  this  was  in  fact  the  case  has 

^  The  mean  variation  for  the  three  money  rates  is  easily  seen  to  be 
.8%  and  for  the  commodity  rates  only  .5%.  The  two  "labor"  and 
"  income"  rates  differ  by  .9  and  1.1%  while  the  money  rates  differ 
by  1.3/3-  In  the  New  York  table  which  follows,  the  money  rates 
differ  by  3.0%  and  the  commodity  rates  by  3.2%,  but  the  labor  rates 
by  only  2.2%. 

'-^  For  when  the  future  seems  a  time  of  relative  plenty,  future  goods 
may  be  discounted  at  a  high  rate  and  profits  measured  in  commodi- 
ties may  be  large.  Contrariwise  during  a  period  of  progressive 
scarcity  commodity  interest  may  be  normally  low.  These  theories 
may  seem  to  conflict  with  current  opinion  ;  but  only  when  the  funda- 
mental distinction  is  overlooked  between  a  period  of  plenty  and  a 
period  of  progressive  plenty,  and  between  a  period  of  scarcity  and  a 
period  of  progressive  scarcity.  During  stationary  scarcity  and 
stationary  plenty,  normal  commodity  interest  may  be  high  and  low 
respectively.  But  during  the  transition  from  scarcity  to  plenty  in- 
stead of  running  through  the  intermediate  rates,  commodity  interest 
may  be  normally  higher  than  in  either  of  the  extreme  states.  This 
is  a  case  in  which  "  dynamic"  economics  differ  strikingly  from 
"static"  economics. 


72  American  Economic  Association.  [414 

been  pretty  thoroughly  established  by  the  admirable 
researches  of  David  A.  Wells  ^  and  others,  and  by  the 
statistics  of  wages  compiled  by  Falkner  ^  and  Bowley." 
But  these  considerations  can  scarcely  apply  to  "  labor 
interest"  or  "  income  interest."  A  man  who  borrowed 
the  equivalent  of  a  hundred  days'  income  during  1860-74 
could  pay  it  back  in  a  year  with  the  equivalent  of  101.4 
days'  income,  while  during  1874-91,  for  a  similar  loan 
he  must  return  102.5  days'  income.  This  is  the  opposite 
of  what  we  should  expect  as  the  influence  of  prog- 
ress. It  therefore  seems  safe  to  ascribe  at  least  1.1% 
as  the  borrower's  loss  since  1874,  compm^ed  with  his 
gain  or  loss  before  1874.  It  may  well  be  that  part 
of  this  comparative  loss  for  1874-91  represents  a  gain 
for  1860-74.  If  we  ascribe  half  to  this  gain,  there 
remains  the  other  half,  .5%  or  .6%,  as  loss  during 
1874-91.  Although  this  division  is  quite  arbitrary 
the  conclusion  that  the  borrower's  loss  was  at  least 
Yz'^/o  seems  reasonable  when  we  consider  that  the 
total  comparative  loss,  1.1%,  was  itself  a  minimum. 
But  even  if  we  suppose  the  debtor's  gain  during  the 
former  pferiod  twice  his  loss  during  the  latter,  (a  supposi- 
tion which,  in  view  of  all  the  facts,  must  be  within  the 
claims  of  all  reasonable  monometallists)  we  still  have  a 
minimum  (English)  debtor's  loss  since  1874  of   ^%. 

Combining  the  results  just  given  with  those  of  Chap- 
ter IX  we  see  that  the  average  loss  to  English  borrowers 
during  the  fall  of  prices  since  1874-75  probably  lies  be- 

'  "  Recent  Economic  Changes,"  (New  York,  1890). 

^  Lac.  cit.  These  statistics,  taken  in  connection  with  price  statistics, 
show  that  commodity  wages,  i.  e.,  money  wages  divided  by  the  index 
number  of  prices  (z£/Ao/(?5a/^  unfortunately),  rose  in  England  during 
1860-74  at  the  rate  of  1.8%  per  annum  and  during  1874-91  at  the  rate 
of  2.2%,  while  in  America  for  1849-57  they  fell  2.7%  per  annum  and 
for  1875-91,  rose  2.4%  per  annum. 


415]  Appreciation  and  Interest.  73 


tween  yi'^/o  and  ^%  and  almost  certainly  between  ]A,^o 
and  1%.  The  former  result  may  be  stated  thus, 
y^±  yi%  and  the  latter,  ^  d=  >^%.  We  may  therefore 
say  with  considerable  confidence  that  the  average  debt- 
or's loss  in  England  for  contracts  made  since  1874-75, 
has  been  two-thirds  of  one  per  cent,  per  annum  with  a 
possible  error  of  one-third  of  one  per  cent.  In  other 
words,  the  average  debtor's  loss  could  have  been  cor- 
rected by  a  reduction  in  the  rate  of  interest  of  from 
one-third  of  one  per  cent,  to  one  per  cent. 

§  10. 

For  contracts  made  before  1874,  but  continued  to  the 
present,  the  loss,  since  1874,  must  have  been  greater. 
We  may  therefore  accept  the  former  estimate  of  ^  %  as  a 
lower  limit  or,  to  be  safe,  5^  %.  To  find  an  upper  limit, 
we  recur  to  the  fact  that  India  gold  bonds  purchased 
prior  to  1875  yielded  very  nearly  ^  %  more  interest  than 
the  average  subsequent  to  that  date.  Since  we  have 
estimated  that  the  average  from  1875  was  at  most  i  % 
too  high,  the  average  for  periods  beginning  before  but 
ending  after  1875,  must  have  been  at  most  i  ^  %  too  high, 
for  it  can  scarcely  be  claimed  that  the  rate  of  interest  for 
the  part  of  the  term  of  the  bonds  previous  to  1875  ought 
to  have  been  lower  than  that  for  the  part  subsequent  to 
that  date.  We  therefore  conclude  that,  for  English  con- 
tracts made  before  1874-75,  the  debtor's  loss  since  1874- 
75  has  been  between  ^%  and  i>^%,  i-  <?.,  i  d=  ^%. 

It  follows  that  for  contracts  which  were  made  prior  to 
1874-75  but  subsequently  converted  or  continued  at  a 
lower  rate  of  interest,  the  loss  since  1874-75  was 
I  d=  >^%  per  annum  to  the  date  of  conversion  and 
^  d=  >^  %  since  that  date. 


74 


American  Economic  Association. 


[416 


It  should  be  observed  that  the  foregoing  calculations 
are  based  on  public  prices  of  bonds  and  rates  on  money. 
Interest  on  private  loans  and  farm  mortgages,  although 
influenced  ^  by  the  same  causes  which  affect  the  money 
market,  is  less  flexible  and  the  debtor's  losses  or  gains 
in  these  cases  are  doubtless  somewhat  greater. 


§11. 


The  following  table  gives  the  long  time  averages  for 
New  York.  The  war  period  is  omitted  and  a  nine  years' 
period  of  rising  prices  is  compared  with  a  seventeen 
years'  period  of  falling  prices. 

NEW  YORK  RATES  OF  INTEREST  IN  REI.ATION  TO  RISING  AND 
FALLING  PRICES  AND  WAGES. 


Interest  Appreciation 

Prime  of  money 

Two  name  |           in 

60  days.  jcommodities. 

i  a\ 


Appreciation 
of  money 


labor. 


Virtual 
Interest 
in  com- 
modities. 

j\ 


Virtual 
Interest 


labor. 
h 


1849  -  57  • 
1875-91  . 


8.2^ 
5-2 


-3-8 
+2.0 


-I.I 
-0.4 


4.1 
7-3 


7.0 
4.8 


We  find  for  1849-57  and  1875-91  that  the  money  rates 
were  8.2  and  5.2%,  the  commodity  rates  4.1  and  '].'^%^ 
but  the  labor  rates  7.0  and  4.8%.  We  see  therefore, 
that  in  terms  of  labor,  loans  in  America  have  actually 
been  easier  during  1875-91  than  during  1849-57.  This 
fact  suggests  the  conclusion  that  the  debtor's  loss  in 
America  has  not  been  as  great  as  in  England.     This,  if 

^  See  Appendix,  \  2,  4th  title. 

'^The  average  of  Elliott's  figures  (which  are  not  for  "prime"  paper) 
is  9.2,  but  i.o  has  been  deducted  from  this  average  in  order  that  it 
may  be  properly  compared  with  the  average  of  Robbins'  figures  for 
1S75-91.  The  correction  is  based  on  the  fact  that  i.o  was  the  average 
excess  of  Elliott's  figures  over  Robbins'  during  the  fifteen  years, 
1860-74.     See  Appendix. 


417]  Appreciation  and  Interest.  75 

true,  may  be  due  to  a  more  rapid  rate  of  progress  in  the 
United  States/ 

§  12. 

Four  general  facts  have  now  been  established  : 
(i)  High  and  low  prices  are  directly  correlated  with 
high  and  low  rates  of  interest ;  (2)  Rising  and  falling 
prices  and  wages  are  directly  correlated  with  high  and 
low  rates  of  interest ;  (3)  The  adjustment  of  interest  to 
price  (or  wage)  movements  is  inadequate ;  (4)  This  ad- 
justment is  more  nearly  adequate  for  long  than  for  short 
periods. 

These  facts  are  capable  of  a  common  explanation  ex- 
pressing the  manner  in  which  the  adjustment  referred  to 
takes  place.  Suppose  an  upward  movement  of  prices 
begins.  Business  profits  (measured  in  money)  will  rise, 
for  profits  are  the  difference  between  gross  income  and 
expense,  and  if  both  these  rise,  their  difference  will  also 
rise.  Borrowers  can  now  afford  to  pay  higher  "  money 
interest."  If,  however,  only  a  few  persons  see  this,  the 
interest  will  not  be  fully  adjusted  ^  and  borrowers  will 
realize  an  extra  margin  of  profit  after  deducting  interest 
charges.  This  raises  an  expectation  of  a  similar  profit  in 
the  future  and  this  expectation,  acting  on  the  demand  for 
loans,  will  raise  the  rate  of  interest.     If  the  rise  is  still 

^  See  page  72,  note  2. 

^  It  seems  scarcely  necessary  to  add  as  an  independent  cause  of  mal- 
adjustment the  accumulation  (or  in  the  opposite  case,  depletion)  of 
bank  reserves,  for  this  is  but  another  symptom  of  mal-adjustment  due 
to  imperfect  foresight.  An  increase  of  gold  supply,  as  in  1852-53 
(see  Tooke  and  Newmarch,  "History  of  Prices,"  vol.  V,  p.  345) 
may  first  find  its  way  into  the  loan  market  instead  of  into  circulation. 
But  if  foresight  were  perfect,  this  would  not  happen,  or  if  it  did  hap- 
pen, borrowers  would  immediately  take  it  out  (or  increase  the  liabil- 
ities against  it)  to  avail  themselves  of  the  double  advantage  of  low 
interest  and  high  prospective  profits  from  the  rise  of  prices  about  to 
follow. 


76  American  Economic  Association.  [418 

inadequate  the  process  is  repeated  and  thus  by  continual 
trial  and  error  the  rate  approaches  the  true  adjustment 

When  a  fall  of  prices  begins,  the  reverse  effects  ap- 
pear. Money  profits  fall.  Borrowers  cannot  afford  to 
pay  the  old  rates  of  interest.  If,  through  miscalculation 
they  still  attempt  to  do  this,  it  will  cut  into  their  real 
profits.  Discouraged  thus  for  the  future,  they  will  then 
bid  lower  rates. 

Since  at  the  beginning  of  an  upward  price  movement, 
the  rate  of  interest  is  too  low,  and  at  the  beginning  of  a 
downward  movement  it  is  too  high,^  we  can  understand 
not  only  that  the  averages  for  the  whole  periods  are  im- 
perfectly adjusted  but  that  the  delay  in  the  adjustment 
leaves  a  relatively  low  interest  at  the  beginning  of  an 
ascent  of  prices  and  a  relatively  high  interest  at  the  be- 
ginning of  a  descent.  This  would  explain,  in  part  at 
least,  the  association  of  high  and  low  prices  with  high 
and  low  interest.^  The  fact  that  the  adjustment  is  more 
perfect  for  long  periods  than  for  short,  seems  to  be  be- 
cause in  short  periods,  the  years  of  non-adjustment  at 
the  beginning  occupy  a  larger  relative  part  of  the  whole 
period. 

§  13- 

What  has  been  said  bears  directly  on  the  theory  of 
"credit  cycles."  In  the  view  here  presented  periods  of 
speculation  and  depression  are  the  result  of  ifiequality 
of  foresight.  If  all  persons  underestimated  a  rise  of 
price  in  the  same  degree,  the  non-adjustment  of  interest 
would  merely  produce  a  transfer  of  wealth  from  lender 
to  borrower.  It  would  not  influence  the  volume  of 
loans  (except  so  far  as  the  diversion  of  income  from  one 
person  to  another  would  itself  have  indirect  effects,  such 

'  These  facts  may  be  verified  from  the  tables  in  the  Appendix. 
-"  Cf.  I  2. 


419]  Appreciatio7i  and  Interest.  77 

as  bankruptcy).  Under  such  circumstances  the  rate  of 
interest  would  be  below  the  normal,  but  as  no  one  knows 
it,  no  borrower  borrows  more  and  no  lender  lends  less 
because  of  it.  In  the  actual  world,  however,  foresight 
is  very  unequally  distributed.  Only  a  few  persons  have 
the  faculty  of  always  "  coming  out  where  they  look." 
Now  it  is  precisely  these  persons  who  make  up  the  bor- 
rowing class.  Just  because  of  their  superior  foresight 
society  delegates  to  them  the  management  of  capital. 
It  is  they  who  become  "captains  of  industry."  Their 
share  consists  of  profits  (or  losses)  while  others  lend 
them  capital  and  receive  interest  or  commuted  profits/ 
It  therefore  happens  that  when  prices  are  rising,  bor- 
rowers are  more  apt  to  see  it  than  lenders.  Hence, 
while  the  borrower  is  willing  to  pay  a  higher  interest 
than  before  for  the  same  loan,  lenders  are  willing  to  loan 
the  same  amount  for  the  same  interest.  That  is,  the 
"  demand  schedule "  ^  will  rise  while  the  "  supply 
schedule "  remains  comparatively  unchanged.  This 
will  of  course  raise  the  rate  of  interest.  But  it  will  also 
cause  an  increase  of  loans  and  investments.^  This  con- 
stitutes part  of  the  stimulation  to  business  which  bi- 
metallists  so  much  admire. 

When  prices  fall,  borrowers  see  that  they  cannot  em- 
ploy "  money"  productively  except  on  easier  terms,  but 
lenders  do  not  see  why  the  terms  should  be  made  easier. 
In  consequence  "  entrepreneurs"  borrow  less,  enterprise 

^  Hadley,  "  Interest  and  Profits,"  Annals  of  the  American  Acade- 
my of  Political  and  Social  Science ,  November,  1893;  also  "Econom- 
ics," (New  York,  1896),  pp.  116,  269. 

^Marshall,   "Principles,"  Vol.  i,  (3rded.)  p.  171. 

^  That  this  and  the  corresponding  statement  in  the  next  paragraph 
are  borne  out  by  facts  appears  to  be  confirmed,  so  far  as  bank  loans 
and  discounts  are  concerned,  by  Sumner,  "History  of  Banking  in 
the  United  States,"  (New  York,  1896)  and  Juglar,  "  Crises  commer- 
ciales,"   (Paris,  1889). 


78  American  Economic  Association.  [420 

languishes  and,  though  interest  falls  in  consequence  of 
decrease  in  demand,  it  does  not  fall  enough  to  keep  the 
demand  from  decreasing/ 

If  lenders,  as  a  class,  were  possessed  of  greater  fore- 
sight than  borrowers,  we  should  find  trade  languishing 
during  rising  prices  and  stimulated  during  falling  prices. 
In  the  former  case  lenders  would  require  high  interest 
for  fear,  as  in  1871-73,  they  were  lending  at  a  loss  of 
real  wealth,  while  borrowers  would  be  afraid  of  the  ap- 
parently high  rates  charged  ;  and  in  the  reverse  case 
lenders  would  be  eager  to  reap  the  benefits  of  an  appre- 
ciating standard  while  borrowers,  deceived  by  the  appar- 
ently low  rates,  would  rush  in  to  profit  by  them. 

We  see  therefore,  that  while  imperfection  of  foresight 
transfers  wealth  from  creditor  to  debtor  or  the  reverse, 
inequality  of  foresight  produces  over-investment  during 
rising  prices  and  relative  stagnation  during  falling  prices. 
In  the  former  case  society  is  trapped  into  devoting  too 
much  wealth  to  productive  uses  and  in  "  long  production 
processes  "  ^  while  in  the  contrary  case  under-in vestment 
is  the  rule.  It  does  not  seem  possible  to  decide  the  ques- 
tion which  of  the  two  evils  is  the  greater.  ^ 

^  President  Andrews  in  "An  Honest  Dollar,"  p.  3,  writes  :  "Interest 
is  low  .  .  not  because  money  is  abundant  as  before,  but  because  it  is 
not,  its  scarcity  having  induced  fall  of  prices  and  so  paralysis  in  in- 
dustry." But  it  should  be  added,  the  cause  of  the  fall  of  interest  is 
primarily  the  expectatio7i  of  small  profits.     Cf.  infra. 

-  Professor  Bohm-Bawerk,  ("  Positive  Theory  of  Capital,  "  p.  335), 
writes  :  "  Now  the  constant  presence  of  the  agio  on  present  goods  is 
like  a  self-acting  drag  on  the  tendency  to  extend  the  production  pe- 
riod. Extensions  which  would  be  harmful  as  regards  social  provis- 
ion are  thus  made  economically  impossible.  "  During  rising  prices 
this  drag  presses  too  lightly  and  during  falling  prices  too  heavily. 

■^  Bimetallists  usually  claim  that  falling  prices  are  the  greater  evil . 
For  arguments  on  both  sides  see  Professor  Marshall's  evidence, 
Report  on  Depression  of  Trade,  (1886),  p.  422. 


42 1]  Appreciation  and  Interest. 


79 


It  is  believed  that  the  foregoing  theories  correspond 
closely  with  observed  facts  as  to  business  stimulation 
and  depression,  volume  of  loans,  etc.,  but  it  is  not  pro- 
posed here  to  enter  upon  a  special  statement  of  them/ 

Nor  is  this  the  place  to  treat  fully  the  reaction  on  prices 
themselves.  But  it  can  scarcely  be  doubted  that  the 
mal-adjustment  of  interest  is  a  central  feature  in  the 
whole  movement.  Professor  Marshall,  who  recognizes 
fully  the  distinction  between  money  and  commodity  in- 
terest, says  :  ^  "  When  we  come  to  discuss  the  causes  of 
alternating  periods  of  inflation  and  depression  of  com- 
mercial activity,  we  shall  find  that  they  are  intimately 
connected  with  those  variations  in  the  real  rate  of  inter- 
est which  are  caused  by  changes  in  the  purchasing 
power  of  money.  For  when  prices  are  likely  to  rise, 
business  is  inflated,  and  is  managed  recklessly  and  waste- 
fully  ;  those  working  on  borrowed  capital  pay  back  less 
real  value  than  they  borrowed,  and  enrich  themselves  at 
the  expense  of  the  community.  When  afterwards  credit 
is  shaken  and  prices  begin  to  fall,  everyone  wants  to  get 
rid  of  commodities  and  get  hold  of  money  which  is  rap- 
idly rising  in  value  ;  this  makes  prices  fall  all  the  faster, 
and  the  further  fall  makes  credit  shrink  even  more,  and 
thus  for  a  long  time  prices  fall  because  prices  have 
fallen." 

We  would  add  that  these  effects  of  credit  could  not 
follow  if  the  interest  rate  were  perfectly  adjusted.  In- 
terest, rather  than  credit,  appears  as  the  chief  independ- 
ent variable,  objectively  speaking,  though  behind  it  all 
is  imperfection  of  foresight. 

^See  Report  on   Depression   of  Trade,   1886;   and  Report  of  the 
Gold  and  Silver  Commission,  1888. 

2  "  Principles  of  Economics  ",  Vol.  I,  (3rd  ed.,  1S95),  p.  674. 


PART  III.     APPLICATIONS. 
CHAPTER  XL 

THE    BIMETALLIC    CONTROVERSY. 
§1. 

It  is  not  the  purpose  here  to  follow  all  the  arguments 
for  and  against  bimetallism,  but  merely  to  outline  the 
bearing  of  the  foregoing  theories  and  facts  upon  some  of 
those  arguments. 

We  have  seen  in  theory  and  in  practice  that  the  rate 
of  interest  has  tended  to  accommodate  itself  to  the 
changing  value  of  money.  It  follows  that  it  is  quite  er- 
roneous to  obtain  the  amount  of  the  debtor's  or  creditor's 
loss  by  merely  reckoning  the  effect  of  appreciation  or 
depreciation  on  \}i\^  principal  of  the  debt. 

And  yet,  after  all  allowances  are  made,  it  is  true  that 
there  remains  a  net  loss  alternating  between  debtors  and 
creditors  according  to  the  varying  tides  of  credit  and 
prices.  During  the  last  twenty  years  it  has  happened 
that  the  debtor  was  on  the  losing  side.  We  have  estimated 
his  average  loss  at  ^  +  ^  %  per  annum  in  England  and 
probably  less  in  this  country.  This  loss  is  not  inconsid- 
erable. When  looked  at  in  the  aggregate  it  appears 
very  large  indeed.  The  minimum  net  indebtedness 
public  and  private  in  the  United  States  is  given  at  20 
billions,^  on  which  ^%  would  amount  to  130  millions 
per  annum.     But  when  we  compare  this  with  the  aggre- 

'  G.  K.  Holmes,  Bulletin  of  the  Department  of  Labor,  November, 
1895,  p.  48. 


423]  Appreciation  and  Interest.  81 

gate  principal  involved  or  with  the  14  odd  billions  ^  of  an- 
nual product,  it  does  not  seem  capable  of  the  deep  social 
harm  attributed  to  it.  In  fact  it  is  always  misleading  to 
consider  aggregates  except  in  comparison  with  each 
other.  Applied  to  an  ordinary  two  months'  loan  of 
$1,000,  %  %  amounts  to  one  dollar.  In  New  York  city 
the  up-town  banks  often  charge  a  rate  more  than  ^  ^ 
higher  than  that  of  the  down-town  banks  without  driving 
away  customers. 

§  2. 

The  ordinary  estimates  of  the  debtor's  loss  are  based  on 
index  numbers.  From  Sauerbeck's  tables  it  appears  that 
between  1873  ^^^  ^895  money  appreciated  in  terms  of  the 
commodities  selected,  79.0%,  which  is  at  therateof  2.7% 
per  annum.  This  is  from  three  to  eight  times  as  much  as 
the  estimate  we  have  made.  The  error  of  the  ordinary 
calculation  does  not  consist  simply  in  neglecting  the 
matter  of  interest.  The  use  of  index  numbers  is  itself 
subject  to  fatal  objection.^  When  unchecked  by  other 
statistics  they  are  very  misleading.  Not  only  do  we 
reach  different  results  according  to  the  number  of  com- 
modities and  the  method  of  averaging,^  but  the  very  best 
methods  fail  to  give  a  trustworthy  measure  of  ordinary 
domestic  purchasing  power,  both  because  they  are  based 
on  wholesale  instead  of  retail  prices  and  because  they 
ignore  expenditure  for  house  rent  and  for  labor  and 
domestic  service,  which,  in  the  family  budgets  of  those 
who  borrow  and  lend,  must   form  a  very  large  item. 

^  Edward  Atkinson,  Engineering  Magazine,  December,  1895. 

^  The  reader  is  reminded  that,  though  we  have  used  index  numbers 
to  determine  "  commodity  interest, "^we  have  not  employed  them  to 
estimate  the  debtor's  loss. 

^See  articles  by  Edgeworth,  Sauerbeck  and  Pierson  in  the  ^co«o w«^ 
Journal,  March,  June,  and  September,  1895,  and  March,  1896. 


82  American  Economic  Association.  [424 

Moreover  to  know  the  purchasing  power  of  a  dollar  does 
not  enable  us  to  know  the  "  subjective  value"  or  mar- 
ginal utility  of  money.  The  number  of  dollars  at  com- 
mand ( /.  ^.,  money  incomes)  must  also  be  considered. 
And  even  were  our  knowledge  complete  as  to  the 
marginal  utility  of  money  as  well  as  its  purchasing 
power,  we  should  be  as  far  as  ever  from  solving  the 
problem  of  the  debtor's  loss.  The  question  is  not  one 
of  appreciation  of  gold  relatively  to  commodities  or  to 
labor  or  any  other  standard.  It  is,  as  we  have  seen, 
exclusively  a  question  of  foresight  and  of  the  degree  of 
adaptation  of  the  rate  of  interest. 

§3- 

It  scarcely  needs  to  be  pointed  out  that  bimetallism 
can  only  affect  unpaid  debts.  We  should  therefore 
clearly  recognize  the  fact  that  the  most  of  the  loss  which 
debtors  have  suffered  since  1873  has  already  passed  be- 
yond the  reach  of  remedy.  Of  the  residuum  the  losses 
vary  with  the  duration  of  the  debt.  On  debts  three 
years  old  the  loss  in  England  is  probably  about  two  per 
cent.,  on  those  six  years  old  about  four  per  cent.,  and  so  on. 
Moreover,  on  debts  contracted  before  the  fall  of  prices 
began,  the  annual  rate  of  loss  was  greater,  being  proba- 
bly, as  we  have  seen,  i  ±  /^%.  Most  such  debts,  how- 
ever, including  even  national  debts,  have  received  part 
of  the  benefit  of  low  interest  through  extensive  con- 
versions. 

Now  bimetallism,  if  adopted,  so  far  from  rectifying 
gains  and  losses,  would  simply  increase  the  inequalities. 
If  it  resulted  in  debasing  the  standard  ten  per  cent,  it 
might  exactly  remedy  debts  fifteen  years  old,  but  the 
correction  would  be  too  small   for  those  older  and  too 


425]  Appreciation  and  Interest.  83 

large  for  those  younger  than  fifteen  years.  The  latter 
form  the  great  bulk  of  existing  indebtedness.  The 
average  life  of  a  farm  mortgage  is  4^  years  ^  so  that 
the  average  age  of  mortgages  now  in  force  would  be 
about  ^Yi  years.  Bank  loans  run  only  a  few  days  or 
months.  These  and  other  short  time  loans  make  up 
some  sixty  per  cent,  of  existing  indebtedness.^  The  re- 
mainder consists  of  railway  and  government  loans  and 
few  of  them  extend  back  to  1873.^  '^\i^  chief  and 
dominant  effect  of  debasement  would  therefore  be  to 
defraud  the  lender  of  today  and  yesterday.*  The  older 
debts,  for  which  the  remedy  is  designed,  no  longer  exist. 

§4. 

But  even  if  bimetallism  or  any  other  financial  scheme 
could  so  scale  debts  as  exactly  to  counteract  the  losses 
connected  with  the  fall  of  prices,  the  ethics  of  such  an 
arrangement  ought  not  to  go  unmentioned.  The  fact 
that  debtors  have  lost  does  not  imply  that  they  have  suf- 
fered an  injustice.  If  a  man  insures  his  house  and  it 
burns  the  next  day  the  insurance  company  suffers  a  loss 
but  not  an  injustice.  If  the  company  should  ask  for  leg- 
islative relief  on  the  ground  that  it  had  not  expected  so 
sudden  a  termination  of  its  policy,  that  the  fire  was 
brought  about  by  causes  which  it  could  not  possibly 
foresee  or  provide  against,  it  would  be  laughed  to  scorn. 
"  Keep  your  contract "  would  be  the  reply.  It  would 
^  'Eleventh  Census,  Bulletin  71. 
'^Holmes,  loc.  cit. 

^  Probably  mucb  less  than  one- fourth  for  American  railways.  This 
estimate  is  made  by  looking  over  all  the  funded  indebtedness  whose 
dates  of  issue  are  given  in  the  "  Ofl&cial  Intelligencer"  for  1894. 

*  For  effects  on  "Social  Classes,"  see  article  by  Professor  H.  W. 
Farnani,  Yale  Review^  August,  1895,  p.  183. 


84  American  Economic  Association.  [426 

make  no  difference  if  the  fires  were  nniversal,  and  every 
insurance  company  lost.  Those  who  assume  the  risks 
must  take  the  consequences.  A  farmer  mortgages  his 
farm  and  agrees  to  pay  $1,000  and  5%  interest.  By  the 
terms  of  the  agreement  he  takes  all  risks  as  to  what  the 
dollar  will  buy  of  wheat  or  anything  else.  He  may  lose 
and  all  farmers  may  lose  and  the  causes  may  be  in  India 
or  Australia  or  in  the  sun  spots,  but  we  can  scarcely  af- 
ford to  surrender  the  ancient  principle  of  the  Inviolabil- 
ity of  Contracts,  through  sympathy  with  the  misfortunes 
of  any  individual  man  or  group  of  men.  That  elements 
of  risk  exist  in  every  contract  and  that  this  risk  implies 
responsibility  are  too  often  ignored.  President  Andrews 
writes  ^ :  "  Increase  in  the  value  of  money  robs  debtors. 
It  forces  every  one  of  them  to  pay  more  than  he  cove- 
nanted [!] — not  more  dollars  but  more  value."  But 
contracts  which  call  for  money  do  not  call  for  "  value  " 
any  more  than  contracts  to  deliver  wheat  call  for  money. 
If  a  man  had  agreed  a  year  ago  to  deliver  10,000  bricks 
to  a  builder  at  a  fixed  price,  he  would  not  be  justified  in 
offering  only  9,000  on  the  ground  that  the  price  had 
gone  up.  A  contract  to  pay  "  value  "  would  be  a  legal 
curiosity,  and  the  court  which  should  attempt  to  inter- 
pret it  would  hear  an  interesting  assortment  of  defini- 
tions from  our  leading  economists. 

Closely  associated  with  the  principle  of  the  Inviolabil- 
ity of  Contracts  is  the  principle  against  retro-active 
laws,  and  in  particular,  against  laws  which  alter  existing 
contracts.  The  world  has  reached  these  principles 
through  a  long  and  weary  struggle  and  much  costly  ex- 
perience with  repudiation  and  the  abuses  of  legal  tender. 
The  burden  of  proof  rests  on  those  who  would  revert 
^  "  An  Honest  Dollar,  "p.  2. 


427]  Appreciation  and  Interest.  85 

to  these  experiments  for  the  sake  of  any  benefits  from 
bimetallism.  Surely  the  practical  reasons  against  such 
a  course  are  obvious  enough.  When  once  a  government 
has  undertaken  to  "  correct  "  debtor's  losses,  it  will  not 
stop  at  one  attempt.  History  teaches  that  a  nation  once 
embarked  on  such  a  policy  never  keeps  its  most  solemn 
word  as  to  where  it  shall  leave  off.  ^  Creditors  will  fear 
to  lend  except  at  usurious  rates  and  the  debtor  of  the  fu- 
ture will  pay  dearly  for  the  emancipation  of  the  debtor 
of  the  present.^ 

§5- 

To  those  who  claim  that  the  cause  of  the  aggravation 
of  debts  was  governmental  action  in  the  first  instance 
and  that  therefore  it  is  now  a  fit  subject  for  governmental 
correction,  the  obvious  answer  is  that  this  does  not  ap- 
ply to  the  great  mass  of  existing  contracts  which  have 
been  formed  since  demonetization. 

Finally  it  may  be  objected  that  the  gold  standard  as 
such  is  on  the  side  of  creditors  as  against  debtors  because 
it  is  an  appreciating  standard  and  according  to  our  own 
statistics  the  debtor  usually  wins  in  rising  and  loses 
in  falling  prices. 

Such  reasoning,  however,  is  entirely  fallacious.  The 
fallacy  is  of  the  same  kind  as  that  contained  in  the  fa- 
cetious advice  to  young  speculators  :  "  Buy  when  stocks 
are  low  and  sell  when  they  are  high.  "  It  is  easy  to 
prophesy  after  the  event ;  investors  in  India  silver  bonds 
have  lost  for  twenty  years  but  this  does  not  prove  that 
the  present  price  of  rupee  paper  is  still  too  high.  If  it 
did,  London  brokers  would  be  the  first  to  know  it  and 

1  Shaw,  "  History  of  the  Currency,"  (18951  ;  also  Sumner,  "  History 
of  American  Currency,"  p.  331. 

2  See  the  writer's  "Would  Bimetallism  benefit  the  'Debtor  Class'?" 
The  Bond  Record,  April,  1896. 


86  American  Economic  Association.  [428 

correct  it.  We  cannot  therefore  say  the  "  present 
arrangement  is  all  in  favor  of  tlie  creditor  and  against 
the  debtor.  "  What  bimetallist  will  risk  his  reputation 
in  predicting  the  course  of  prices  and  interest  in  the 
next  twenty  years  ?  If  prices  rise,  we  may  with  great 
probability  predict  that  the  debtor  will  vrin.  If  they 
fall,  he  will  lose.     But  who  knows  which  is  the  true 

§6. 

Legislation  to  offset  the  effects  of  a  fall  of  prices  in 
the  past  is  wrong,  because  retro-active.  Legislation  to 
offset  the  effects  of  a  fall  in  the  future  is  absurd,  because 
we  cannot  know  there  will  be  a  fall,  and  if  we  could, 
there  would  be  no  need  of  legislation. 

There  remains  to  be  considered  legislation  for  the 
purpose  of  making  the  monetar}-  unit  less  variable,  that 
is,  not  to  prevent  something  which  we  can  foresee  but 
to  prevent  something  which  we  cannot  foresee.  Such 
a  reason  for  monetan,-  legislation  must  be  recognized 
at  once  as  thoroughly  sound.  But  it  applies  equally 
well  to  "  symmetallism"  ^  and  other  plans  -  for  monetary 
reform. 

That  bimetallism    ( as  long  as  it  lasted)^  would  be 

'  Edgewortli,  "  Thoughts  on  monetary  reform",  Economic  loiirnal, 
September,  1S95. 

'E.g.,  the  multiple  standard  propounded  by  Lowe,  1S22,  and 
Scrope,  1833,  and  advocated  by  Jevor.s,  "Money  and  the  Mechanism 
of  Exchange",  p.  328,  and  "Investigations",  p.  123,  and  by  Marshall, 
Report  of  the  Commission  on  Depression  of  Trade,  p.  423  ;  also 
the  various  forms  of  double  standard  suggested  by  Marshall,  ibid., 
Edgeworth,  ibid.,  Hertzka  "  Das  iuternationale  Wahrungsproblems," 
1892,  and  Stokes,  "Joint  Metallism,"  (1S95)  ;  also  the  various  forms  of 
elastic  currenc}*  suggested  by  Professor  Walras,  "  Theorie  de  la 
Monnaie",  (Lausanne,  iSS5i,  by  Secretary  Windom  and  others. 

'See  the  writer's  "  Mechanics  of  Bimetallism,"  Economic  Journal, 
September,  1894. 


429]  Appreciation  and  Interest.  87 

more  dependable  than  monometallism  is  probable  on 
a  priori  grounds,  but  the  statistics  which  we  have  given 
seem  to  reveal  as  great  uncertainty  in  price  movements 
before  1873  ^^  since.  It  is  indeed  a  large  question 
how  far  au}^  sort  of  monetary'  reform  could  remedy  the 
matter  ;  for  the  expansion  and  contraction  of  credit 
might  be  almost  as  violent  and  mischievous  as  ever.  It 
may  be  however,  that  "  the  evils  .  .  are  so  great  that  it 
is  worth  while  to  do  much  in  order  to  diminish  them  a 
little."  ^  If  a  more  stable  and  less  expensive  ^  monetary 
standard  can  be  found,  it  will  be  an  inestimable  boon  to 
the  civilized  world.  As  an  improvement  on  the  two 
single  standards  now  existing,  bimetallism,  launched  at 
the  market  ratio,  ma}"  be  worth  serious  consideration. 
But  the  proposal  now  before  the  world  is  bimetallism  at 
15/^  or  16  to  I.  Such  bimetallism  means  debasement 
of  the  standard  of  any  single  country-  which  attempts  it. 
If  international,  it  means  debasement  in  gold  standard 
countries,  and  a  violent  contraction  and  appreciation  in 
silver  standard  countries.  In  no  other  wa}-  could  the  in- 
fluence of  the  legal  ratio  on  the  market  ratio  be  felt.  We 
should  witness  not  only  losses  to  creditors  in  the  former 
countries  but  losses  to  debtors  in  the  latter,  and  these 
losses  would  be  far  in  excess  of  those  which  we  have 
found  to  follow  from  the  slow"  and  half  foreseen  appre- 
ciation of  the  last  tv^'enty  years. 

'Marshall,  "Principles  of  Economics"  Vol.  I,  3rded.,  (1895),  p.  674. 

*Jevons,  "Investigations,"  p.  104;  "  .  .  the  very  scarcity  of  gold 
is  its  recommendation  .  .  in  itself  gold  digging  has  ever  seemed 
to  me  almost  a  dead  loss  of  labor  as  regards  the  -world  in  general." 
Also  Lexis,  Economic  Journal,  June,  1S95,  p.  276. 


CHAPTER  XII. 

THE   THEORY   OF   INTEREST. 

§1. 

The  relation  existing  between  interest  and  appreciation 
implies  that  the  rate  of  interest  is  relative  to  the  standard 
in  which  it  is  expressed.  Economists,  from  Hume  and 
Adam  Smith  down,  seem  to  have  considered  the  money 
element  entirely  eliminated  from  the  rate  of  interest  by 
the  simple  fact  that,  in  the  last  analysis,  it  is  capital, 
not  money,  which  is  loaned  and  returned.  But,  as 
has  been  seen,  we  can  identify  the  rate  of  interest  in 
terms  of  capital  with  the  rate  of  interest  in  terms  of 
money  only  when  the  price  ratio  between  money  and 
capital  remains  constant. 

The  first  thought  suggested  by  this  fact  is  to  dis- 
tinguish between  "  nominal"  and  "  real"  interest  in  the 
same  way  that  we  distinguish  between  "  nominal"  and 
"  real"  wages.  This  seems  to  be  the  thought  of  all  the 
writers  who  have  touched  on  the  subject.  Professor 
Marshall  in  fact  uses  the  words  "  real"  and  "  nominal."^ 
de  Haas  speaks  of  the  effect  of  the  appreciation  or  de- 
preciation of  money  as  introducing  a  "  third  element"^ 
into  the  rate  of  interest.  This  "  element"  is  to  be  added 
to  or  subtracted  from  the  sum  of  the  other  two  elements, 
which  are  a  payment  for  capital  (or  the  rate  of  interest 
proper)  and  a  payment  for  insurance.     John  Stuart  Mill 

'  "Principles  of  Economics,"  Vol.  I,  3rd  ed.  (1S95),  P674. 

''■Journal  of  the  Royal  Statistical  Society,  March,  1S89.  It  will 
be  seen  from  the  formula  i-l-7"=(i  +  0  (i  +  a)  that  the  "third 
element"  is  not  a  mere  additive  term. 


43 1]  Appreciation  aiid  hiterest.  89 

and  the  eighteentli  century  pamphleteer  ^  were  evidently 
thinking  of  a  normal  rate  of  in  terest  in  coin  to  which 
a  certain  extra  charge  is  to  be  added  if  paper  depreciates 
in  reference  to  coin.  Finally  the  article  of  Professor 
John  B.  Clark  ^  is  devoted  chiefly  to  a  search  for  an  ab- 
solute standard  to  which  we  may  refer  any  monetary 
appreciation  or  depreciation  and  in  which  therefore 
"  real"  interest  could  be  expressed.  It  is  not  denied 
that  the  words  "  real"  and  "  nominal"  are  very  conven- 
ient terms  and  for  a  rough  and  ready  expression  may 
serve  a  useful  purpose.  But  the  mere  distinction  be- 
tween "real"  and  "nominal"  is  quite  inadequate  for  a 
true  and  accurate  statement  of  the  case.^ 

If  we  seek  to  eliminate  the  money  element  by  ex- 
pressing the  rate  of  interest  in  terms  of  real  "  capital," 
we  are  immediately  confronted  with  the  fact  that  no  two 
forms  of  capital  maintain  or  are  expected  to  maintain  a 
constant  price  ratio.  There  are  therefore  just  as  many 
rates  of  interest  on  capital  as  there  are  forms  of  capital 
diverging  in  value.  Even  if  we  could  find  an  ideal  in- 
dex number  for  capital  in  general  or  for  commodities, 
there  are  other  kinds  of  interest  which  might  also  claim 
the  title  of  "  real  "  ;  we  refer  to  "  labor"  and  "  income"* 
interest.  It  cannot  even  be  claimed  that  relative 
changes  in  prices,  wages  and  incomes  are  abnormal  phe- 
nomena, or  incident  only  to  a  dynamic  society.  Even 
in  the  most  ideal  stationary  state,  the  mere  changes  in 
seasons  would  make  interest  between  summer  and  winter 

'  See  Chapter  I,  §  2. 

"^  Political  Science  Quarterly,  September,  1895. 

*  Professor  Edgeworth  (  "  Variations  in  Value  of  Monetary  Stand- 
ards", Report  of  the  British  Association  for  the  Advancement  of 
Science,  1889,  p.  163),  exhibits  seven  kinds  of  standards  for  deferred 
payments. 

*  See  Chapter  X,  ??  8,  9. 


90  Ama-ican  Economic  Association.  [432 

low  in  terms  of  summer  precincts  sncli  as  frnit,  and  high 
in  terms  of  winter  products  such  as  ice.  The  rate  of 
interest  is,  as  Professor  Bohm-Bawerk  shows,  an  agio  on 
present  goods  exchanged  for  future  goods  of  the  same 
kind.  It  is  a  simple  corollary  of  this  theorem,  though 
Professor  Bohm-Bawerk  does  not  express  it,  that  this 
agio  may  be  in  theory  and  must  be  in  practice  a  different 
agio  for  each  separate  kind  of  goods. 

§   2. 

But,  it  may  be  urged,  surely  there  is  some  invariable 
standard  conceivable  in  theory  if  not  determinable  in 
practice,  which  may  serve  for  a  base  line  of  apprecia- 
tion and  depreciation  for  all  goods  and  money,  and  in 
terms  of  which  we  may  express  a  "real"  rate  of  interest. 
This  brings  us  to  the  question  of  an  absolute  standard 
of  value.  But  here  we  encounter  another  difficulty. 
Such  an  absolute  standard  will  differ  with  each  indi- 
vidual.^ The  fact  that  a  dollar  is  a  smaller  unit  to  a 
millionaire  than  to  a  poor  laborer,  has  as  its  consequence 
that  as  the  millionaire  grows  poorer  his  dollar  grows 
larger  while  as  the  laborer  grows  richer  his  dollar  grows 
smaller.  On  account  of  such  changes  in  personal  for- 
tunes the  dollar,  however  defined,  will  be  constantly 
appreciating  and  depreciating  in  different  degrees  among 
different  men  and  classes.  In  fact  the  phenomenon  of 
borrowing  and  lending  is  to  some  extent  itself  a  conse- 
quence of  the  different  degrees  in  which  money  appre- 
ciates or  depreciates  to  borrower  and  lender. 

1  Marshall,  "Principles,"  Vol.  I,  (3rd  ed.),  p.  198,  and  Royal  Com- 
mission on  Depression  of  Trade,  1SS6,  p.  423 ;  also  the  writer's 
"Mathematical  Investigations  in  the  Theory  of  Value  and  Prices," 
Transactions  of  the  Connectictd  Academy,  (New  Haven,  1892). 


433]  Appreciation  and  hiterest.  91 


In  addition  to  the  differences  already  mentioned,  there 
is  a  different  rate  of  interest  for  each  period  of  time  con- 
sidered. The  rate  in  any  given  goods  for  a  loan  con- 
tracted to-day  and  payable  one  year  hence  is  the  agio  of 
this  year's  over  next  year's  goods ;  the  rate  for  a  -loan  to 
be  contracted  one  year  hence  and  payable  two  years 
hence  is  the  agio  (  reckoned  to-day  )  of  next  year's  goods 
over  the  goods  of  the  succeeding  year  and  so  on.  The 
rate  for  a  loan  contracted  to-day  and  payable  two  years 
hence  is  the  "  actuarial  average  "  ^  of  the  two  previous 
rates.  There  is  no  reason  why  these  three  rates  and 
others  constructed  in  the  same  manner  should  not  be  all 
different.^ 

§  4- 

We  thus  reach  a  multiple  theory  of  interest.  Our 
results  are,  first,  that  different  standards  have  in  general 
different  rates  of  interest ;  secondly,  that  of  the  numer- 
ous standards  thus  possible  a  different  one  is  "  absolute  " 
for  each  individual ;  thirdly,  that  in  each  standard  there 
will  be  a  different  rate  for  dijfferent  periods  of  time.^ 

'  See  Chapter  V,  §  4. 

"^  Professsor  Bohm-Bawerk  (  "Positive  Theory,  "  p.  280 ),  in  showing 
how  "arbitrage  transactions"  tend  to  equalize  rates,  tacitly  assumes 
that  the  iirst  two  rates  above  mentioned  are  equal  and  only  proves 
that  in  that  case  the  third  will  be  equal  to  the  first. 

^  Besides  these  three  sorts  of  variations  there  are  others  due  to  un- 
certainties of  various  kinds.  In  the  theory  of  Part  I,  we  have  only 
considered  the  case  where  the  relative  divergence  of  two  standards  is 
foreknown  with  certainty.  To  complete  the  picture  it  is  necessary  to 
introduce  the  theory  of  probabilities  as  applicable  to  economics. 
(See  Marshall's  "Principles",  p.  198,  note,  and  211,  note.)  When  this 
is  done  it  will  also  explain  the  diiferent  terms  for  call  loans,  30  days,  60 
days  loans,  etc.,  as  well  as  for  different  degrees  of  security.  Although 
in  the  latter  case  we  may  distinguish  pure  interest  as  the  rate  for  per- 
fect security,  yet  the  surplus  above  this  sum  is  not  simple  insurance- 
It  is  not  a  certain  sum  paid  for  a  contingent  loss  but  it  is  itself  con- 


92  American  Economic  Association.  [434 

In  actual  business  experience  none  of  these  three  sorts 
of  differences  attract  attention.  The  third  is  usually 
very  slight  in  amount.  ^  The  second  is  not  reducible  to 
statistical  measurement ;  while  the  first  escapes  notice 
because  of  the  habit  of  reckoning- always  in  money.  In 
a  few  cases,  as  for  Indian  and  Chinese  bonds,  London 
brokers  must  have  occasion  to  note  the  fact  that  3%  in 
silver  is  usually  not  equivalent  to  3  ^  in  gold,  but  even 
in  such  cases  the  gold  rate  is  thought  of  as  "  the  "  rate. 
So  also  speculative  contracts  in  wheat,  land,  etc.,  and 
ordinary  loans,  which  are  really  advances  of  stock,  ma- 
terials, and  other  forms  of  capital,  are  always  translated 
into  money  and  their  essential  nature  as  involving  inde- 
pendent standards  is  concealed.  But  the  economist,  who 
so  often  finds  it  necessary  to  forsake  the  language  of 
money  and  speak  in  terms  of  the  things  which  money 
measures,  must  here  also  recognize  the  fact  that  the  rate 
of  interest  in  terms  of  money  is  simply  a  common  repre- 
sentative of  multiform  rates  in  other  standards. 

These  rates  are  mutually  connected  and  our  task  has 
been  merely  to  state  the  law  of  that  connection.  We 
have  not  attempted  the  bolder  task  of  explaining  the 
rates  themselves.  Such  an  explanation  constitutes  the 
"  theory  of  interest "  in  the  more  usual  sense  and  forms 
the  subject  of  Professor  Bohm-Bawerk's  masterly  trea- 
tise. The  relation  between  the  two  branches  of  the  sub- 
ject may  be  pictured  as  somewhat  analogous  to  that  be- 
tween the  theory  of  relative  prices  and  the  theory  of 
price  levels. 

tingeut ;  and,  what  is  more  important  here,  it  is  not  a  present  sum  but 
a  series  of  deferred  sums  and  as  such  is  itself  subject  to  the  principles 
of  pure  interest.  It  follows  that  we  cannot  strike  out  the  "  insurance 
element  "  as  a  mere  additive  term  with  which  the  theory  of  interest 
proper  has  no  concern.     A  complete  theory  has  yet  to  be  written. 

'  For  a  supposable  case  of  great  variation,  see  Chapter  V,  ^  ?  i,  2. 


APPENDIX. 

STATISTICAL  DATA. 
§  I. 

The  writer  has  found  so  much  difficulty  in  securing 
a  long  series  of  yearly  averages  for  rates  on  "  money  ", 
that  the  results  are  here  presented  in  the  hope  that  they 
may  be  of  use  to  others. 


YEARLY  AVERAGE  RATES  OF  INTEREST  ON  "  MONEY."  i 


London 


Berlin. 


New  York. 


Calcutta 


'  (LI  C  rt  I 


Tokyo. 


Shanghai. 


1824 
1825 
1826 
1S27 
1828 
1829 
1830 
1831 
1832 
1833 
1834 
1835 
1836 
1837 
1838 

1839 
1840 
1841 
1842 
1843 
1844 
1845 
1846 
1847 
1848 
1849 
1850 
1851 
1852 
1853 
1854 
1855 
1856 
1857 
1858 
1859 
i860 
1861 
1862 
1863 
1864 
1865 
1866 
1867 
1868 
1869 
1870 
1871 
1872 
1873 
1874 
1875 
1876 
1877 
1878 
1879 
1880 
188 1 
1882 
1883 
1884 
1S85 
1886 
1887 
ib88 
1889 
1890 
1891 
1892 

1893 
1894 
1895 


I  3-5 

3-9 

4-5 

3-3 

30 

3-4 

,  2.8 

!  3-7 

I  3-1 

!  2.7 

3-4 
3-7 
4.2 

4-5 
3-0 
5-1 
50 
4-9 
3-3 
2.2 
2.1 
3-0 
3-8 
5-9 
3-2 
2.3 
2.2 

3-1 
1-9 

3.7 
4-9 
4-7 
5-9 
7-1 
3.1 
25 
4.1 
5-5 
2.4 
4-3 
7-4 
4.6 
6.7 
2.3 
1.8 

3-0 
3-1 
2.7 
3-8 
4-5 
3-5 
3-0 
2.2 

2.3 
3-5 
1.8 
2.2 
2.9 
3-4 
3-0 
2.6 
2.0 

2-1 
2.4 
2.4 
2.7 

3-7 
2.5 
1-5 


3-9 
9-7 
6.5 
7.0 
6.1 

4-9 
4.2 
4.2 
5-1 
5-5 
8.7 
6.9 

9-1 
5-1 
5.8 
6.0 
5-7 
4-7 
50 
3-9 
6.2 

5-7 
6.8 
8.4 
5-3 
6.3 
4.6 
5-3 
6.6 
6.8 
6.4 
5-4 
6.0 
5-6 
5-5 
7.0 
5-8 
3-1 
3-5 
4-9 
5-4 
4-3 


iS. 

!i8 

14- 

18 

14- 

18 

14. 

14 

12. 

ii4 

12. 

'14 

12. 

i,S 

10. 

^3 

II. 

15 

11.  |i6 

13-  '17 

14-  ;i7 
10.     17 

7.9  II 

12.  16 

13.  II 
8.8  9 
9.0    8 

10.  I  9 

TO.      10 

11.  II 

9-4    9 

8.3!  8 
7.8i  7 

9-3;  • 

9.6  . 


I  The  London,   Berlin  and  Paris  market  rates  are   on  first  class  merchants' 


437]  Appreciation  arid  Interest.  95 

All  the  rates  are  entered  in  the  foregoing  table  as 
rates  of  "interest,"  though  the  rates  for  the  Banks  of 
England,  Germany  and  France  are  rates  of  discount. 
The  two  are  not  quite  equivalent  but,  for  the  purposes 
of  the  foregoing  work,  the  distinction  between  them  is 
unnecessary  because,  in  a  continuous  series,  the  error,  if 
any,  affects  all  items  nearly  alike  and  thus  cancels  itself 
out  in  the  comparisons. 

Had  it  been  necessary,  some  of  the  tables  could  have 
been  extended  back.  Thus  the  Bank  of  England  rate 
could  be  given  to  1696  but  it  was  too  inflexible  to  be  of 
use.  The  Berlin  and  Paris  bank  rates  could  also  be  ex- 
tended and  the  Paris  market  rate  could  be  given  from 
1861  (except  for  1870  and  1871)  from  data  in  Wi^  Econo- 
mist. 

bills.  The  figures  for  1824-58  are  from  the  evidence  of  D.  B.  Chapman  before  the 
Committee  on  the  Bank  Act,  1857,  Sess.  2,  X,  pt.  I,  p.  463,  (also  reprinted  in 
Hunt's  Merchants'  Magazine.  Vol.  41,  (1859)  P-  95)-  Th";  remaining  figures  are 
compiled  from  the  Economist.  For  those  for  18S4-94,  the  writer  is  indebted  to 
Professor  F.  M.  Taylor  of  Michigan  University,  who  had  collected  them,  from  the 
Economist  for  a  different  purpose.  The  Bank  of  England  rates  for  1824-43  are  re- 
duced from  Burdett's  "  Ofiicial  Intelligencer,"  (1894),  p.  1,771.  The  remaining  ones 
for  England,  Germany  and  France  are  reduced  from  those  given  in  the  Report 
of  the  Royal  Commission  on  Depression  of  Trade,  1886,  p.  373,  and  the  Economist. 
They  represent  the  bank  "minimum."  The  New  York  rates  are  taken,  the  first 
two  columns,  from  a  table  by  E.  B.  Elliott  (afterward  government  actuary)  in 
the  (New  York)  Banker's  Magazine,  1S74.  The  quotations  given  as  "60  days" 
apparently  included  single  name  paper.  The  third  column  to  1890  is  compiled 
from  a  diagram  of  highest  and  lowest  monthly  rates  prepared  at  Yale  college  by 
Mr.  G.  P.  Robbins  of  the  class  of  1891,  and  has  been  completed  from  the  Financial 
Review,  by  averaging  the  highest  and  lowest  weekly  rates.  It  has  been 
found  impossible  to  extend  the  table  back  beyond  1849,  as  the  rates  are  not 
systematically  reported.  The  Calcutta  rates  are  the  minimum  of  the  Bank  of 
Bengal  and  have  been  kindly  furnished  by  Messrs.  Place,  Siddons  and  Gough, 
brokers,  of  Calcutta.  The  market  rates  of  Tokyo  are  averages  of  the  highest  and 
lowest  rates  of  each  year,  furnished  by  Mr.  Ichi  Hara  of  the  Bank  of  Japan, 
Tokyo.  The  bank  rates  are  for  the  Tokyo  and  Yokohama  Co-operative  Bank  and 
were  translated  by  Mr.  Sakata,  student  at  Yale,  from  a  history  of  Japan  by 
Zenshiro  Tsuboya.  The  tables  for  Shanghai  have  been  procured  through  the 
kindness  of  Mr.  F.  W.  "Williams  of  the  department  of  Oriental  History  of  Yale 
University,  who  obtained  them  from  Mr.  J.  F.  Seaman  of  Shanghai.  The  first 
column  contains  the  rates  ruling  in  the  native  market,  and  the  second,  those  of 
the  Hong  Kong  and  Shanghai  bank  (under  English  control)  on  overdrawn  cur- 
rent accounts,  a  species  of  demand  loans  and  the  ordinary  form  of  lending  in 
Shanghai.  Mr.  Seaman  was  told  that  the  market  rates  cannot  be  extended  back 
beyond  1S85,  as  the  books  of  the  Chinese  banks  for  previous  years  are  burnt. 

2  This  rate  is  only  from  September  when  the  operation  of  the  Bank  Act  began, 
previous  to  this  the  custom  of  the  bank  was  to  have  a  uniform  rate  for  all  loans. 


gS  American  Economic  Association.  [438 

Many  of  the  sources  from  which  the  table  has  been 
drawn  also  contain  other  information  such  as  the  rates 
for  Vienna,  Amsterdam  and  other  money  centres,  the 
weekly  or  monthly  rates,  the  variation  with  the  seasons, 
the  number  of  changes  of  the  Bank  Minimum,  etc. 

§2. 

Of  sources  not  mentioned  in  the  above  note,  the  chief 
which  the  writer  has  encountered  are  : 

Adolf  Soetbeer,    "  Materiallen  zur  Wabrungsfrage,"   (Berlin,   1S86), 
p.  78. 

Covers  1851-S5  for  Banks  of  England,  France  and  Germany,  and  mar- 
ket rates  of  Hamburg  and  Vienna. 
Austrian    Government,    "  Tabellen    zur    Wabrungsfrage,"    (Vienna, 
1S92),  pp.  204-6.     (A  second  edition  bas  just  appeared,  1896). 
Covers  1S61-91  for  banks  of  Italy,  England,  France,  Germany,  Austria, 
Belgium  and  Holland,  and  market  rates  in  Vienna,  iS6q-gi. 

W.  Stanley  Jevons,  "  Investigations  in  Currency  and  Finance,"  (Lon- 
don, 1884). 

Contains  diagram  for  prices  of  consols  and  3  per  cent,  stock  from  1731, 
and  minimum  rate  of  interest  in  London  from  1824  ;  also  monthly  vari- 
ation in  rate  of  interest,  p.  10.  The  diagram  for  the  price  of  consols 
shows  that  during  the  middle  and  first  half  of  the  eighteenth  century 
the  interest  realized  was  almost  as  low  as  in  the  present  generation. 
This  was  a  period  of  falling  prices. 
Eleventb  Census  of  the  United  Slates,  Bulletin  71  (on  real  estate 
mortgages,  1880-89). 

This  is  probably  the  most  elaborate  series  of  interest  averages  ever 
constructed.    If  these  averages  be  compared  with  the  course  of  prices 
during  the  average  term  of  the  contracts  (five  years),  it  will  be  found 
in  nearly  every  case  that  interest  is  high  or  low  according  to  the  degree 
of  the  rise  or  fall  in  prices. 
"Viscomte  G.  D'Avenel,   "  Histoire  economique  de  la  propriety,  des 
Salaires,  des  Denr^es  et  de  tous  les  Prix  en  gdn^ral  depuis  I'an  1200 
jusqu'en  I'an  1800,"   (Paris,  1894),  vol.  II,  p.  882. 

This  work  contains  also  tables  of  the  purchasing  power  of  money,  but 
neither  the  interest  nor  price  statistics  are  sufficiently  exact  or  detailed 
for  use  in  the  foregoing  study. 

Tooke,  "History  of  Prices,"  and 

Tooke  and  Newmarcb,  "  History  of  Prices  from  1793  to  1856." 

G.   Winter,    "Zur  Gescbicbte  des  Zinsfusses  in   Mittelalter,"   Zeit- 

schrift fiir  Social und  Wirlschaftsgeschichte,  (Weimar),  1895,1V,  2. 

Arthur  Crump,   "English  Manual  of  Banking,"   (4th  ed.,  London, 

1879).  PP-  Mi-4- 

Gives  Bank  of  England  rates  for  1694-1876. 


439]  Appreciation  and  hiterest. 


97 


Alph.  Courtois  fils,  "  Histoire  des  Banques  en  France,"  (Paris,  1881). 
Gives  rate  of  interest  at  the  Bank  of  France,  iSoo-1880. 

Wilhelm  von  Lucam,   "  Die  Oesterreichische  Nationalbank  wahrend 
der  Dauer  des  dritten  Privilegiums,"  (Vienna,  1876),  p.  121. 
Gives  rates  for  Bank  of  Austria,  1817-75. 

"Jahrbiicher  fiir  Nationalokonomie  und  Statistik,"  February,  1896, 
pp.  282-83. 

Gives  bank  and  market  rates  for  London,  Paris,  Berlin,  Amsterdam, 
Brussels,  Vienna  and  St.  Petersburg,  1841-80  by  decades,  and  1881-95  by 
years. 

"  Handworterbuch  der  Staatswissenschaften,"  Article  "Banken." 
Gives  rates  for  Bank  of  Prussia  and  Germany,  iS47-89i^^for  Bank 
of  Austria,  1878-89  ;  Switzerland,  1883-88.  <^^^ 

A.  N.  Kiaer,  "  Om  seddelbanker, "  (Kristiania,  1877). 

Contains  diagram  of  bank  rates  at  Kristiania,  Stockholm  and  Kjoben- 
havn,  1853-76. 

M.  G.  Mullhall,  "Dictionary  of  Statistics,"  (London,   1892),  pp.  76, 
607. 

Gives  rates  for  countries  of  Europe  by  five  and  ten  year  periods  since 
1850. 

William  Farr,  "On  the  valuation  of  railroads,  telegraphs,"  ^ic,  Jour- 
nal of  the  Royal  Statistical  Society,  September,  1S76,  pp.  464-530, 

"  Report  of  the  New  England  Mutual  Life  Ins.  Co.,"  Boston,  1890. 
Gives  rates  realized  by  twenty  representative  insurance  companies  for 
1869-88,  and  for  Massachusetts  savings  banks  for  1877-89,  and  bank  divi- 
dends in  Boston,  New  York  and  Philadelphia.  The  rates  realized  by  the 
insurance  companies  for  the  twenty  years,  1869-88,  inclusive,  were  6.0, 
5.9,  6.1,  6.2,  6.5,  6.2,  6.5,  6.1,  5.6,  5.1,  5.0,  4.8,  4.8,  5.1,  5.1,  4.7,  4.7,  4.9,  4.7,  4.6, 
respectively.  These  represent  (if  the  -writer  mistakes  not)  the  average 
rates  earned  on  the  par  value  of  investments  of  all  ages,  some  old,  some 
new,  some  terminable  soon  and  others  having  many  years  to  run.  For 
this  reason  they  are  of  little  or  no  use  for  the  foregoing  study. 

Robert  GifFen,  "Essay  in  Finance,"  second  series,  (London,   1886), 

P-  37- 

Seasonal  variations  of  interest  in  connection  with  bank  reserves,  etc. 

F.  M.  Taylor,  ' '  Do  we  want  an  Elastic  Currency  ? ' '  Political  Science 
Quarterly,  March,  1896,  pp.  133-157. 

Gives  diagram  showing  the  relation  of  surplus  reserves  and  rates  of 
discount ;  also  seasonal  variation  of  rate  of  discount. 

R.  H.  Inglis  Palgrave,  "Analysis  of  the  Transactions  of  the  Bank  of 
England,"  (London,  1874). 

Gives  rates,  1844-72,  and  seasonal  variation,  1844-56  and  1857-72.  Shows 
dependence  of  rate  on  ratio  of  reserve  to  liabilities. 

R.  H.  Inglis  Palgrave,  "Bank-rate  in  England,  France,  and  Germany, 
1844-78 ;  with  remarks  on  the  causes  which  influence  the  rate  of 
interest  charged ;  and  an  analysis  of  the  accounts  of  the  Bank  of 
England,"  (London,  1880). 

R.  H.  Inglis  Palgrave,  (London)  Bankers'  Magazine,  March,  April, 
May,  1878. 

Number  of  changes  in  bank  rates  of  England,  France,  and  Germany. 


^8  American  Economic  Association.  [446 

Theodor  Hertzka,  "Wahrung  und  Handel,"  (Vienna,  1S76). 

Gives  the  number  of  weeks  each  rate  lasted  for  the  Banks  of  England, 
France,  Germany,  and  Austria  during  1844-73. 

George  Clare,  "Money  Market  Primer,"  (London,  1S91). 

Diagrams  for  seasonal  variations  of  interest,  bank  reserves,  etc. 

Commercial  and  Financial  Statistics  of  British  India.     Second  issue, 
(Government  Printing  OfSce,  Calcutta),  1894,  pp.  354-64. 

Monthly  Discount,  Bank  of  Bengal,  1861-94,  and  average  quotations  of 
government  securities  held  in  I,ondon. 

Report  of  the  Secretary  of  the  Treasury,  1893,  p.  401. 
Report  of  the  Comptroller  of  Currency,  1894,  p.  179. 
H.  W.  Farnam,  "Some  Effects  of  Falling  Prices,"  Yale  Review,  Au- 
gust, 1895. 

The  last  three  references  contain  statistics  of  rates  of  interest  realized 
on  some  United  States  Government  bonds. 

R.  A.  Bayley,   "National  Loans  of  the  United  States",  (Government 
Printing  Ofl&ce,  Washington,  1882). 

Gives  rates  of  interest  and  price  of  issue  of  all  United  States  loans  from 
July  4,  1776,  to  June  30,  1880. 

"Dictionaire  des  Finances,"  Article  "Interet." 
Gives  rates  at  vrhich  France  has  borrowed. 

The  following  tables  of  index  numbers  are  appended 
in  order  that  the  reader  may  verify  the  periods  of  rising 
and  falling  prices  which  have  been  discussed  in  Chapters 
X  and  for  the  reason  that  many  of  the  tables,  notably 
those  for  India,  Japan  and  China,  have  not  hitherto 
been  accessible  to  most  readers. 


INDSX  NUMBERS  IN  SEIVEN  COUNTRIES.i 


England. 


1824 
1825 
1826 
1827 
182S 
1829 
1830 
1831 
1832 
1833 
1834 
1835 
1836 
1837 
1838 

1839 
1840 
1841 
1842 
1843 
1844 
1845 
1846 
1847 
1848 
1849 
1850 
1851 
1852 
1853 
1854 
1855 
1856 
1857 
1858 

1859 
i860 
1861 
1852 
1863 
1864 
1865 
1866 
1867 
1868 
1869 
1870 
1871 
1872 
1873 
1874 
1875 
1876 
1877 
1878 
1879 
1880 
188 1 
1882 
1883 
1884 
1885 
1886 
1887 


1890 
1891 
1892 
1893 
1894 
1895 


105 
124 
108 
108 
97 
95 
97 
98 

93 
90 

93 
96 
103 

lOI 

loi 
no 
104 

102 
90 
85 
83 


94 
82 

77 
77 
79 
781 

95 
102 
loi 

lOI 

105 
91 
94 
99 
98 

lOI 

103 
105 

lOI 
102 
100 

99 
98 
96 
100 
109 
III 
102 
96 
95 
94 
87 


113 


134 
129 


Germany. 


100 
102 
114 
121 
124 
123 
130 
114 
116 
121 
118 
123 
125 
129 
123 
126 
124 
122 
123 
123 
127 
136 
138 
136 
130 
128 
128 
121 
117 
122 
121 
122 
122 
114 
109 
104 
102 
102 
106 
108 
109I 
106 
102 
92 
91 


United  States. 


100 
118 
127 
129 
112 

115 
100 

95 
97 
94 
94 
105 
103 

94 
87 
85 
82 


79 


90 

84 
85 
88 
95 
95 
88 

83 
89 

99 
98 
105 
105 
109 
112 
114 

"3 

103 
100 

94 
104 
132 
172 
232 
188 
166 
174 
152 
144 
136 
132 
129 
130 
129 
123 
114 
105 
95 
105 
108 
109 
107 
103 
93 
93 
94 
96 
98 
94 
94 


83 


100 
100 
loi 
104 
119 

134 
149 

156 
164 
165 
167 
167 
166 
167 
166 
162 
158 
151 
144 
141 
139 
143 
151 
153 
159 
155 
156 
156 
157 
158 
163 
168 
169 


India. 


95 
99 
121 
125 
119 
112 
99 

96 
97 
95 
99 
loi 
104 
107 
103 
104 

"5 
119 


Japan. 


104 
104 
105 
102 

105 
114 

145 
160 

175 
159 
130 
116 
116 
107 
109 
112 
116 
124 
123 
124 
129 


China. 


100 
103 
III 
10 1 
106 
III 
105 
no 
108 
103 
104 
105 
107 
105 
100 
105 
104 
104 
108 
109 


1  For  England,  the  figures  for  prices  are  from  Jevons  and  Sauerbeck.    Those 


lOO  American  Economic  Associatio7i.  [442 

from  Sauerbeck  begin  in  1852.  They  are  taken  from  the  Aldrich  report  (I,  247) 
and  from  the  Journal  of  the  Royal  Statistical  Society,  March,  1S96.  Those  from 
Jevons  are  from  1824  to  1852  inclusive,  and  are  taken  from  his  "  Investigitions  in 
Currency  and  Finance."  In  order  to  make  ihe  tables  of  Jevons  and  Sauerbeck 
continuous,  Jevons'  number  for  1S52  is  called  78  (i.  e.,  Sauerbeck's  for  that  year) 
instead  of  65  as  given  in  the  "Investigations,"  and  all  the  other  numbers  are 
raised  in  the  ratio  78  :  65.  Jevons'  figures  are  for  forty  commodities  ;  Sauerbeck's 
for  fortj'-five.  The  index  numbers  for  English  wages  are  from  the  article  by 
Bowley  in  the  Journal  of  the  Royal  Statistical  Soceety,  June,  1895. 

The  German  numbers  are  from  Soetbeer,  Heinz  and  Conrad.  Those  for  1851-gi 
inclusive,  are  from  Soetbeer,  continued  by  Heinz,  and  given  in  the  Aldrich  report 
(I,  294)  ;  those  for  1891-95  inclusive,  are  from  Conrad,  as  given  in  "his  JahrbUcher^ 
1S94-6,  but  are  all  magnified  in  the  ratio  109  :  98  in  order  to  make  the  series  con- 
tinuous, since  Heinz's  figure  for  1891  is  109,  and  Conrad's  98.  The  statistics  of 
Soetbeer  and  Heinz  cover  114  commodities. 

The  French  numbers  are  from  the  Aldrich  report  (I,  335)  founded  on  the  figures 
of  the  Commission  permanente  des  valeurs.     They  cover  only  sixteen  articles. 

The  figures  for  the  United  States  are  those  of  Professor  Falkner  in  the  Aldrich 
report  (I,  9,  13),  the  weighted  averages  (last  method)  being  employed. 

Those  for  India,  Japan  and  China  are  from  the  Japanese  Report  of  the  Com- 
mission for  investigation  of  monetary  systems,  1S95.  The  writer  is  under  great 
obligations  to  Mr.  Ichi  Hara,  of  Tokyo,  for  a  copy  of  the  report,  and  to  Mr. 
Sakata  of  Yale  University,  for  translating  the  tables. 

That  for  India  is  an  average  of  three  tables  which  cover  respectively  twentj'-one 
articles  of  export,  sixteen  articles  of  export  priced  at  Calcutta  and  Bombay,  and 
eight  grains  at  Bombay.  That  for  Japan  is  an  average  of  three  tables,  of  forty- 
two  articles  at  Tokyo,  sixteen  at  Osaka  and  thirty. one  articles  of  export.  That 
for  China  is  an  average  of  three  tables,  of  twenty  inland  commodities,  seventeen 
articles  of  export  and  fifteen  food-stuffs  in  Shanghai. 

The  tables  for  India  were  based  on  official  statistics,  those  for  Japan  on  in- 
formation from  guilds  and  merchants,  and  those  for  China  on  the  reports  of  the 
consuls  of  Japan  and  England  (Mr.  Jameson)  in  China. 

In  the  Japanese  report  the  prices  for  Japan  are  reduced  to  a  silver  basis.  As 
silver  was  at  a  premium  up  to  1S85  it  has  been  necessary  in  constructing  the 
above  table  to  reconvert  into  currency  by  applj'ing  the  premium  for  1873-85,  viz.: 
4,  4i  3)  I1  3)  10)  32,  48,  70,  57,  26,  9,  5  per  cent,  respectively. 


THE  MACPHILLAS^  COfVIPANY'S  NEW  PUBLSCATIONS. 


the;  PRINCIPI^ES  of  SOCIOI^OGY.  An  Analysis  of  the  Phenomena  of  Association 
and  of  Social  Organization.  By  Franklin  Henry  Giddings,  M.A..  Professor  of 
Sociology  in  Columbia  University  in  the  City  of  New  York.  Second  Edition.  8vo, 
cloth,  $2,-00,  tie t.     {Columbia  University  Press.) 

MUNICIPAL  HOME  RULE.  A  Study  in  Administration.  By  Frank  J.  Goodnow, 
A.M.,  Ivly-D.,  Professor  of  Administrative  Law  in  Columbia,  author  of  "Compara- 
tive Administrative  Law."     i2mo,  cloth,  I1.50,  net.     {Colutnbia  University  Press.) 

STATISTICS  AND  SOCIOLOGY.  Science  and  Statistics.  Part  I.  By  Richmond 
Mayo-Smith,  Professor  of  Political  Economy  and  Social  Science  in  Columbia  Col- 
lege.   Svo,  cloth,  I3.00,  net.     {Columbia  University  Press.) 

INTRODUCTION  TO  POLITICAL  SCIENCE.  Two  Series  of  Lectures  by  Sir  John  R. 
Seeley,  K.C.M.G.,  Litt.D..  Regius  Professor  of  Modern  History  in  the  University 
of  Cambridge,  etc.     i2mo,  cloth,  pp.  xi  +  387,  $1.50. 

THE  CHILD  AND  CHILDHOOD  IN  FOLK-THOUGHT  (The  Child  in  Primitive  Cul- 
ture). By  Alexander  Francis  Chamberlain,  A.M.,  Ph.D.,  Lectures  on  Anthro- 
pology in  Clark  Universit3f  ;  sometime  Fellow  in  Modern  Languages  in  Universitj^ 
College,  Toronto  ;  Fellow  of  the  American  Association  for  the  Advancement  of 
Science,  etc.,  etc.    Svo,  cloth,  $3.00,  net. 

PRINCIPLES  OF  THE  ENGLISH  LAW  OF  CONTRACT,  AND  OF  AGENCY  IN  ITS 
RELATION  TO  CONTRACT,  By  Sir  William  R.  Anson,  Bart.,  D.C.L.,  of  the 
Inner  Temple,  Barrister-at-Law,  Warden  of  All  Souls'  College,  Oxford.  Eighth 
Edition.  First  American  Copyright  Edition.  Edited,  with  American  Notes,  by 
Ernest  W.  Huffcut,  Professor  of  Law  in  the  Cornell  University  School  of  Law. 
Svo,  cloth,  pp.  456,  $3.00,  net. 

AN  EXAMINATION  OF  THE  NATURE  OF  THE  STATE.  A  Study  in  Political  Phil- 
osophy. By  Westel  Woodbury  Willoughby,  Ph.D.,  Lecturer  in  Political  Phil- 
osophy in  the  Johns  Hopkins  University.    Svo,  cloth,  $3.00. 

THE  KING'S  PEACE  :  A  HISTORICAL  SKETCH  OF  THE  ENGLISH  LAW  COURTS. 
By  F.  A.  Inderwick,  Q.C,  Author  of  "Side  Lights  on  the  Stuarts."  With  15  illus- 
trations and  I  map.     i2rao,  cloth,  pp.  xxiii  -|-  254,  ^1.50. 

***  New  Volume  of  Social  England  Series,   edited  by  Kenelm  D.  Cotes,  M.A. 
Oxon, 

WOMAN  UNDER  MONASTICISM.  Chapters  on  Saint  Lore  and  Convent  Life  between 
A.D.  500  and  A.D.  1500.     By  Lina  Ickenstein.     Svo.  cloth,  §4.00,  ?iei. 

THE  HISTORY  OF  THE  DECLINE  AND  FALL  OF  THE  ROMAN  EMPIRE.  By 
Edv^^ard  Gibbon,  Edited  in  seven  volumes.  With  Introduction,  Notes,  Appen- 
dices, and  Index,  by  J.  B.  Bury',  M.A.,  Hon.  L-H.D.  of  Durham  ;  Fellow  and 
Tutor  of  Trinity  College,  Dublin;  Professor  of  Modern  History  in  Dublin  Univer- 
sity.    i2mo,  cloth.  Vol.  I,  $2.00.     {To  be  completed  in  seven  volumes,  each  $2.00.) 

THE  THEORY  OF  THE  DIVINE  RIGHT  OF  KINGS,  By  J  Neville  Figgis,  M.A. 
Lecturer  of  History  in  St.  Catherine's  College,  Cambridge.  Prince  Consort  Disser 
tation,  1S92.  i2mo,  cloth,  pp.  xiv  -|-  304,  $1.25,  net.  Catnbridge  Historical  Essays 
No.  IX, 

GREEK  PAPYRI.— An  Alexandrian  Erotic  Fragment  and  other  Greek  Papyri,  chiefly 
Ptolemaic.  Edited  by  Bernard  P.  Grenfell,  M.A.,  sometime  Craven  Fellow  of 
Oxford  ;  Fellow  of  Queen's  College.  With  Frontispiece.  Svo,  cloth,  pp.  xi  +  129, 
S3.00;  net. 


THE  riACMILLAN  COMPANY,  66  FIFTH  AVE.,  NEW  YORK. 


PERIODS     OF     EUROPEAN     HISTORY. 

General  Editor,  ARTHUR  HASSALL,  M.A. 

PERIOD  IV.— THE  BALANCE  OF  POWER— 1715-1759.  By  Arthur 
Hassall,  M.A.,  Student  of  Christ  Church,  Oxford,  author  of  "Boling- 
broke,"  "  Louis  XIV,  aud  the  Zeuith  of  the  French  Monarchy,"  etc. 
i2mo,  cloth,  |i.6o,  net. 


CAMBRIDGE     HISTORICAL     SERIES. 
General  Editor,  G.  W.  PROTHERO,  M.A.,  Fellow  of  Kings  College,  etc. 

THE  UNITED  STATES  OF  AMERICA— 1765-1S65.  By  Edward  Chan- 
NING,  Ph.D.,  Assistant  Professor  of  History  in  Harvard  University. 
lamo,  cloth,  I1.50,  net. 


THE  ARUERICAN  ECOr^OSVISC  ASSOCBATION. 

Vol.  X,  Nos.  5-6. 

LETTERS  OF  DAVID  RICARDO  TO  JOHN  RAMSEY  McCULLOCH.  Edited  with  An- 
notations b5'-  J.  H.  Hollander.  Ph.D.,  Instructor  in  Economics,  Johns  Hopkins 
University.     Svo,  paper  cover,  Si. 25,  net ;  or  bound  in  cloth,  $2.00.  7iet. 

Vol.  XI,  No.  i. 

RACE  TRAITS  AND  TENDENCIES  OF  THE  AMERICAN  NEGRO.  By  Frederick 
I,.  Hoffman,  F.S.S.,  Statistican  to  the  Prudential  Insurance  Co.  of  America. 


ISflCHOLSON.— STRIKES  AND  SOCIAL  PLOBLEMS.  By  J.  Shield  Nicholson,  M.A., 
D.Sc.j  Profesor  of  Political  Economy  in  the  University  of  Edinburgh.     i2mo,  cloth, 

pp.  viii  +  238,  51.25. 

BOOTH.— LIFE  AND  LABOR  OF  THE  PEOPLE  IN  LONDON.  Edited  by  Charles 
Booth.  Vol.  II.— POPULATION  CLASSIFIED  BY  TRADES.  (Continued.)  Svo, 
cloth,  pp.  viii  +  50S,  $3.00. 

MALI/OCK.— CLASSES  AND  MASSES,  OR  WEALTH,  WAGES  AND  WELFARE  IN 
THE  UNITED  KINGDOM.  A  handbook  of  Social  Facts  for  Political  Thinkers 
and  Speakers.    By  W.  H.  Mallock.     i2mo,  cloth,  $1.25. 

THE  UNIVERSITIES  OF  EUROPE  IN  THE  MIDDLE  AGES.  By  Hastings 
Rashdall.  M. A.,  Fellow  and  Lecturer  of  Hertford  College,  Oxford.  3  vols.,  Svo, 
cloth.     Vol  I,  pp.  562  ;  Vol.  II,  pp.  832,  $14.00.  net. 

Contents. — Vol.  I :  Salerno,  Bologna,  Paris  ;  Vol.  II,  Part  i :  Ital3',  Spain,  France, 
Germany,  Scotland,  etc.  ;  Vol.  II,  Part  2  :  English  Universities,  Student  Life. 

THE  GROWTH  OF  BRITISH  POLICY:  AN  HISTORICAL  ESSAY.  By  Sir  J.  R. 
Seeley,  Litt.D.,  K.C.M.G.,  formerly  Regius  Professor  of  Jloderu  Historj' in  the 
University  of  Cambridge.  With  Portrait.  "Two  vols.,  i2mo,  cloth,  pp.  (Vol.  I.)xxiv 
+  436  ;  (Vol.  II.)  403,  $3.50,  net. 


THE  MACMILLAN  COHPANY,  66  FIFTH  AVE.,  NEW  YORK. 


Economic  Classics 

—  EDITED   BY  — 

\A/.  J.  ASML-EY,   IVl.A,., 

Professor  of  Economic  History   in   Harvard  University,    late  Fellow  of 
Li7icoln  College,  Oxford. 
16mo.    Cloth.    75  cents  each. 


THE  MERCANTILE  SYSTEM  AND  ITS  HISTORICAL  SIGNIFI- 
CANCE. Illustrated  chiefly  from  Prussian  History.  Being  a  Chapter 
from  "  Studien  ueber  die  wirthschaftliche  politik  Friedrichs  des  Gros- 
sen."     By  Gustav  SchmollKR. 

ADAM  SMITH.  Select  Chapters  and  Passages  from  "The  Wealth  of 
Nations."     12  mo.     pp.  2S5.     I/imp  cloth.     Price  75  cents. 

DAVID  RICARDO.  The  first  six  chapters  of  "The  Principles  of  Politi- 
cal Economy,"  etc. 

T.  R.  MALTHUS.  Parallel  Chapters  from  the  First  and  Second  Edition 
of  "An  Essay  on  the  Principle  of  Population." 

ENGLAND'S   TREASURE   BY    FORRAIGN    TRADE.      By  THOMAS 

MUN,   1664. 

PEASANT  RENTS.  Being  the  First  Half  of  an  Essay  on  the  Distribu- 
tion of  Wealth  and  on  the  Sources  of  Taxation.  By  Richard  Jone;s, 
1831. 

OTHER  VOLUHES  IN  PREPARATION. 


The    Century    Science    Series 

ISdited  by  Sir  Henry  'B,.  Roscoe,  D.C.I,.,  F.R.S. 
12010.    Cloth.    Each  $1.25. 


Jamks  Clerk  Maxwell  and  Modern  Physics, 

By  R.  T.  Glazenbrook,  F.R.S.,  Fellow  of  Trinity  College,  Cambridge,  University  I,ec- 
tnrer  in  Mathematics,  and  Assistant  Director  of  Cavendish  I^aboratory. 

With  Portrait. 

JUSTUS  VON  LIEBIG:  HIS  LIFE  AND  WORK  (1803-1873).  By 
W.  A.  Shenstone;,  F.I.C. 

THE  HERSCHSLS  AND  MODERN  ASTRONOMY.  By  Miss  AGNES 
M.  CtERKE. 

CHARLES  LYELL:  HIS  LIFE  AND  WORK.  By  Rev.  Prof.  T.  G. 
BONNEY,  F.R.S. 

JOHN  DALTON  AND  THE  RISE  OF  MODERN  CHEMISTRY. 
Bv  Sir  HENRY  E.  RoscoE,  F.R.S. 

MAJOR  RENNELL,  F.R.S.,  AND  THE  RISE  OF  ENGLISH 
GEOGRAPHY.  By  CLEMENTS  R.  Markham,  C.B.,  F.R.S.,  Presi- 
dent of  the  Royal  Geographical  Society. 

OTHER  VOLUHES  IN  PREPARATION. 


THE  MACMILLAN  COMPANY,     66  Fifth  Ave. 


The  WIacmillan  COMPANY'S  Recently  Published  Biographies,  Etc. 


BARNARD.— MEMOIRS  OF  FREDERICK  A.  P.  BARNARD,  D.D.,  LL.D.,  L.H.D.,  D.C.L., 
Tenth  President  of  Columbia  College  in  the  Citj'  of  New  York.  By  John  Fulton. 
8vo,  cloth.     {Calumbia  University  Psess.) 

"It  is  Manning  himself  as  revealed  in  his  correspondence." 

LIFE  OF  CARDINAL  MANNING,  Archbishop  of  Westminister.  By  Edmund  Sheri- 
dan PuRCELL,  Member  of  the  Romon  Adademy  of  Letters.  With  Portraits. 
Second  Edition.    Two  vols.,  Svo.,  cloth,  $6.00. 

Vol.    I. — Manning  as  an  Anglican. 
Vol.  II.— Manning  as  a  Catholic. 

LIFE,  LETTERS,  AND  WORK  OF  LOUIS  AGASSIZ.  By  Jules  Marcou.  With  Por- 
traits and  Illustrations.    Two  vols.,  crown  Svo,  $4.00. 

THE  LETTERS  OF  MATTHEW  ARNOLD,  1S48-1888.  Collected  and  arranged  by 
George  W.  E.  Russell.  Third  Edition.  Two  vols.,  i2mo,  cloth,  $3.00.  (^Uniform 
vrith  Matthew  Arnold's  Complete  Works.) 

THE  LIFE  AND  LETTERS  OF  EDWARD  A.  FREEMAN,  D.C.L.,  LL.D.      By  W.   R. 

W.  Stephens,  B.D.,  Dean  of  Winchester,  author  of  "  The  Life  and  Letters  of  Dean 
Hook,"  etc.     With  Portraits,  etc.     Two  vols.,  crown  Svo,  cloth,  $7,00. 

JOHN  KNOX.  A  Biography.  By  P.  Hume  Brown,  author  of  "George  Buchanan, 
Humanist  and  Reformer."  With  Plate  Frontispiece  and  other  Illustrations.  In 
two  vols.,  demy  Svo,  $7.50. 

THE  LETTERS  OF  EDWARD  FITZGERALD  TO  FANNY  KEMBLE.  Collected  and 
Edited,  with  Notes,  by  William  Aldis  Wright.     i2mo,  cloth,  $1.50. 

SIR  SAMUEL  BAKER.  A  Memoir.  By  T.  Douglas  Murray,  F.R.G.S.,  Executor  to 
the  late  Samuel  Baker,  and  A.  Silva  White,  Hon.  F.R.G.S.    Svo,  buckram,  J6.00. 

MIGUEL  DE  CERVANTES  :  HIS  LIFE  AND  WORKS.  By  Henry  Edward  Watts. 
New  Edition.  Revised  and  Enlarged,  with  complete  Bibliography  and  Index.  Por- 
trait.    Crown  Svo,  cloth,  $2.50. 

SONIA  KOVALEVSKY  :  Biography  and  Autobiography.  I.  Memoir  by  A.  C.  Leffler 
(Edgren),  Duchessa  Ds  Cajanello.  II.  Reminiscences  of  Childhood.  Written  by 
herself.  Translated  into  English  by  Louise  von  Cossel.  With  Portraits.  i2mo. 
cloth,  $1.25. 

THE  PRIVATE  LIFE  OF  WARREN  HASTINGS,  By  Sir  Charles  Lawson,  Fellow 
of  the  University  of  Madras,  etc.  With  3  Photogravure  Portraits  and  78  Illustra- 
tions.   Svo,  cloth,  $3.50. 

DUNDONNALD.  By  the  Hon.  John  W.  Fortescue.  i2mo,  cloth,  uncut,  75  cents  ;  cloth, 
limp,  60  cents.     [E?igh'sh  Men  of  Action  Series. ) 

RENAN.— BROTHER  AND  SISTER.  A  Blemoir  and  the  letters  of  Ernest  and  Henri- 
ette  Renan.    Translated  by  Lady  Mary  Loyd.     i2mo,  cloth,  $2.50. 


THE  riACniLLAN  COflPANY,  66  FIFTH  AVE.,  NEW  YORK. 


AN  IMPORTANT  HISTORICAL  WORK. 

Economic  History  of  Virginia  in  the  Seventeenth  Century. 

An  Inquiry  into  the  Material  Condition  of  the  People,  based  upon  original  and  contem- 
poraneous records.    By  Philip  Alexander  Bruce,  author  of  "The  Plantation 
Negro  as  a   Freeman,"   and    Corresponding  Secretary   of    the   Virginia 
Historical  Society.     With   a   Map.     2  vols.,  crown   8vo,  $6.00  net. 

''  A  book  that  may  be  fairly  termed  unique  from  the  viewpoint  of  exhaustive  research 
in  its  particular  field.  .  .  .  The  mass  as  well  as  the  extraordinary  variet5r  of  material 
which  enters  into  the  economic  history  of  Virginia  in  the  colonial  period  will  be  appre- 
ciated when  we  point  out  that  these  two  volumes,  each  of  which  comprises  some  600 
pages,  only  cover  the  first  ninety-three  years  of  the  community's  existence." — The  Sun. 

"  Iucomparabl3' the  most  valuable  contribution  to  the  social  and  economic  literature  of 
Virginia This  superb  work  not  only  establishes  Mr.  Bruce's  right  to  fame  in  au- 
thorship, but  it  imposes  on  him  as  a  logical  sequence  the  obligation  of  continuing  his 
labors.  The  Economic  History  of  Virginia  will  find  a  place  not  only  in  the  public  and 
private  libraries  of  Virginia,  but  also  in  the  libraries  of  the  whole  country." — Pittsburgh 
Index  A p heal. 

The  Child  and  Childhood  in  Folk-Thought. 

( The  Child  in  Primitive  Culttire. ) 

By  Alexander  Francis  Chamberlain,  M.A.,  Ph.D.,  IvCcturer  on  Anthropology  in 

Clark  University  ;  sometime  Fellow  in  Modern  Languages  in  University  College, 

Toronto ;  Fellow  of  the  American  Association  for  the  Advancement  of 

Science,  etc.,  etc.    8vo,  cloth,  $3.00  net. 


New  Edition  of  Gibboti. 
The  History  of  the  Decline  and  Fall  of  the  Roman  Empire. 

By  Edward  Gibbon.    Edited  in  Seven  Volumes.    V/ith  Introduction,  Notes,  Appendices 
and  Index,  by  J.  B.  Bury,  M.A.,  Hon.  I^.H.D.  of  Dvirham,  Fellow  and  Tutor  of 
Trinity  College,  Dublin,  Professor  of  Modern  Hi,story  in  Dublin  Univer- 
sity.    i2mo,  cloth,  vol.  I,  $2.00.     {To  be  completed  in  seven  volumes^ 
each   $2.oo) 


The  Growth  of  British  Policy :    An  Historical  Essay. 

By  Sir  J.  R.  Seeley,  Litt.D.,  K.C.M.G.,  formerly  Regius  Professor  of  Modern  History  in 
the  University  of  Cambrido:e.     With  Portrait.     Two  vols.,  i2mo,  cloth, 
pp.  (Vol.  I)  xxiv+436  ;  (Vol.  II)  403,  §3.50,  net. 
"The  work  is  one  of  the  most  important  in  the  field  of  historical  literature." — Boston 
Daily  Advertiser. 

Works  by  Jatnes  Bryce,  M.P.,  D.C.L. 
The  American  Commonwealth. 

2  vols.  Large  i2mo.  Third  Edition.  Revised  throughout.  Price  $4.00  net. 
^'  His  work  rises  at  once  to  an  eminent  place  among  studies  of  great  nations  and  their 
institutions.  It  is,  so  far  as  America  goes,  a  work  unique  in  scope,  spirit,  and  know^l- 
edge.  There  is  nothing  like  it  anywhere  extant, — nothing  that  approaches  it.  .  .  With- 
out exaggeration  it  may  be  called  the  most  considerable  and  gratifying  tribute  that  has 
yet  been  bestowed  upon  us  by  an  Englishman,  and  perhaps  by  even  England  herself.  .  . 
One  despairs  in  an  attempt  to  give  in  a  single  newspaper  article  an  adequate  account  of 
a  work  so  infused  with  knowledge  and  sparkling  with  suggestion.  .  .  .  Every  thought- 
ful American  will  read  it,  and  "will  long  hold  in  grateful  .remembrance  its  author's 
name." — New  York  Times. 

The  Holy  Roman  Empire. 

Eighth  Edition,  revised  and  enlarged.     i2mo,  $1.00.     Library  Edition,  Svo,  S3.50. 

Social  Institutions  of  the  United  States. 

Reprinted  from  "The  American  Commonwealth."     i2mo,  cloth,  $1.00. 


The  riacmlllan  Company,       66  Fifth  Ave.,  N.  Y. 


The  Quarterly  Journal  of  Economics. 

Published  for  Harvard  University. 


CONTENTS    FOR    JULY,    1896. 

I.  THE  BEGINNINGS  OF  TOWN  UFE  IN  THE  MIDDLE  AGES  .   .    .  W.  J.  Ashley 
II.  INDUSTRIAL  ARBITRATION  ;  ITS  METHODS  AND  LIMITATIONS  .    . 

S.  N.  D.  North 

III.  SHAW'S  HISTORY  OF  CURRENCY CM.  Walsh 

IV.  SUGGESTIONS  FOR  THE  .STUDY  OF  MUNICIPAL  FINANCE,  Frederick  R.  Clow 
NOTES  AND  MEMORANDA. 

FACTS  ABOUT  MONEY  :  A  REJOINDER Willard  Fisher 

RECENT  PUBLICATIONS  UPON  ECONOMICS. 


Extract  from  the  Prefatory  Note  to  the  Index  of  Vols.  I-X : 

"  With  the  number  for  July,  1896,  the  tenth  volume  of  this  fournal  is 
brought  to  a  close.  An  index  of  writers  and  subjects  for  the  series  thus 
closed  has  accordingly  been  prepared  for  the  convenience  of  subscribers, 
and  for  greater  ease  of  consultation  by  students. 

"In  reviewing  the  remarkable  progress  of  economic  discussion  in  the 
United  States  during  the  decade  now  closed,  the  editors  believe  that  they 

may  feel  satisfaction  in  the  share  taken  by  this  fournal The 

progress  in  the  equipment  of  teachers,  in  the  matter  and  methods  of  in- 
struction, in  the  solidity  of  the  contributions  to  learning,  has  been  promot- 
ed in  high  degree  by  the  opportunities  for  a  full  and  free  discussion,  ad- 
dressed not  to  a  miscellaneous  public,  but  to  a  circle  of  critics,  investigators, 
and  well-informed  readers. 

"The  object  of  Xh\s  fonrnal  has  been  to  promote  the  advancement  of 
knowledge  by  inviting  and  assisting  such  discussion,  and  the  editors  hope 
that  a  review  of  the  contents  of  the  series  now  concluded  will  be  found  to 
justify  the  confidence  with  which  they  undertook  this  task  ten  years  ago. 
The  diffusion  of  knowledge  and  the  application  of  principles  maybe  trusted 
in  large  degree  to  take  care  of  themselves,  when  once  the  advance  of  scien- 
tific thought  has  set  in.  It  has  been  the  object  of  the  editors  of  Xlie  fournal 
mainly  to  promote  the  latter  end.  They  will  continue  to  publish  in  the 
future,  as  they  have  done  in  the  past,  papers  which  may  appeal  to  but  a 
limited  number  of  readers.  The}'  will  welcotne,  also,  the  sober  and  unbi- 
ased discussion  of  topics  of  more  immediate  interest,  and  in  all  cases  will 
endeavor  to  present  matter  which  deserves  the  attention  of  scholars  and 
critics.  And  in  this  endeavor  they  again  confidently  ask  the  cooperation  of 
all  who  are  interested  in  the  advancement  of  knowledge  within  the  chosen 
field."  

Books,  periodicals,   and    manuscript   to   be    addressed,   EDITORS    of 
QUARTERLY  JOURNAL  OF  ECONOMICS,  Cambridge,  Mass. 

Business  letters,  etc.,  to  be  addressed,  GEORGE  H.ELLIS,  Publisher, 
141  Franklin  Street,  Boston,  Mass. 


SUBSCRIPTION   $2.00  A  YEAR, 

Specimen  copies  of  the  Journal,  and  the  Index  for  Vols.  I-X,  sent  on  application. 


JOHNS  HOPKINS  UNIVERSITY 

Studies  in  History  and  Politics. 

Edited  by  HERBERT  B.  Adams. 

Fourteenth  Series,  1896.     Subscription,  $3.00. 

CONSTITUTIONAI,  HISTORY  OF  HAWAII.  By  Henry  E.  Chambers.    25  cents. 

CITY  GOVERNMENT  OF  BAI^TIMORE.     By  Thaddeus  P.  Thomas.     25  cents. 

COI^ONIAIv  ORIGINS  OF  NEW  ENGLAND  SENATES.    By  F.  Z,.  Riley.    50  cents. 

SLAVERY  IN  NORTH  CAROLONA  (1663-1865).     By  JOHN  S.  Bassett.     50  cents. 

REPRESENTATION  IN  VIRGINIA.     By  J.  A.  C.  Chandler.     50  cents. 

THE  HIvSTORY  OF  TAXATION  IN  CONNECTICUT  (1636-1776).    ByF.  R.  Jones.     50c. 

SLAVERY  IN  NEW  JERSEY.     By  H.  S.  CooLEY.     50  cents. 

CAUSES  OF  THE  REVOLUTION  OF  16S9  IN  MARYLAND.     By  F.  E.  Sparks. 

Other  papers  will  be  from  time  to  time  announced. 

ANNUAL  SERIES,  1883-1895. 

SERIES  I.— Local  Institutions.    479  pages.    $4.00. 
SERIES  II.— Institutions  and  Economics.    629  pages.    $4.00. 
SERIES  HI.— Maryland,  Virginia  and  Washington.    595  pages.    $4.00. 
SERIES  IV. — Municipal  Government  and  Land  Tenure.    600  pages.    $3.50. 
SERIES  v.— Municipal  Government,  History  and  Politics.    559  pages.    $3.50. 
SERIES  VI.— The  History  of  Co-operation  in  the  United  States.    540  pages.    I3.50. 
SERIES  VII.— Social  Science,  Municipal  and  Federal  Government.    $3,50. 
SERIES  VIII.— History,  Politics  and  Education.    625  pages.    8vo.    I3.50. 
SERIES  IX. — Education,  History  and  Politics.    640  pages.    8vo.    $3.50. 
SERIES  X.— Church  and  State  :  Columbus  and  America.    630  pages.    8vo.    I3.50. 
SERIES  XL— Labor,  Slavery  and  Self-Government.    574  pages.    8vo.    I3.50, 
SERIES  XII.— Institutional  and  Economic  History.    626  pages.    8vo.    $3.50. 
SERIES  XIIL— South  Carolina,  Maryland  and  Virginia.    606  pages.    8vo.    I3.50. 

RECENT  EXTRA  VOLUMES. 

THE  SUPREME  COURT  OF  THE  UNITED  STATES.     By  W.  W,  Willoughby.     124 

pp.     8vo.  cloth.     $1.15. 
THE    INTERCOURSE    BETWEEN    JAPAN    AND    THE   UNITED    STATES.      Inazo 

(Ota)  Nitobe.     198  pp.    8vo.  cloth.    $1.25. 
STATE  AND    FEDERAL   GOVERNMENT  IN  SWITZERLAND.      By  John  Martin 

Vincent.    225  pp.    8vo.  cloth.    $1.50. 
SPANISH  INSTITUTIONS  OF  THE  SOUTHWEST.      By  Frank  W.  Blackmar.     380 

pp.  and  31  plates.     8vo.  cloth.     |2.oo. 
INTRODUCTION   TO   THE   STUDY    OF   THE   CONSTITUTION.      By  M.   M.  Cohn. 

250  pp.     Svo.  cloth.     $1.50. 
THE  OLD  ENGLISH  MANOR.     By  Prof.  C.  M.  Andrews.     2S0  pp.     8vo.  cloth.    $1.50. 
AMERICA  :  ITS   GEOGRAPHICAL   HISTORY,    1492-1S92.     By  Dr.  W.  B.  Scaife.     176 

pp.     Svo.  cloth.    $1.50. 
FLORENTINE  LIFE  DURING  THE  RENAISSANCE-    By  W.  B.  Scaife.    256  pp.    Svo. 

cloth.     I1.50. 
THE  SOUTHERN  QUAKERS  AND  SLAVERY.    By  Stephen  B.  Weeks.    414  pp.    Svo. 

Cloth.    $2.00. 


The  set  of  thirteen  series  is  now  offered  in  a  handsome  library  edition  for  $39.00,  and 
including  subscription  to  the  current  (fourteenth)  series,  $42.00.  The  fourteen  series 
v/ith  fourteen  extra  volumes,  altogether  twenty-eight  volumes,  for  $60.00. 

Orders  should  be  addressed  to 

THE  JOHNS  HOPKINS  PRESS,  BALTIMORE,  MARYLAND. 


RECENT  PUBLICATIONS  OF 

American  Academy  of  Political  &  Social  Science 


CUBA. 

The  Recognition  of  Cuban  Belligerency.     By  Prof.  A.  S.  HersheY. 

Price  IS  cts. 

An  argument  in  its  favor. 

THE  MONEY  QUEvSTlON. 

The  Multiple  Money  Standard.     By  Prof.  J.  Ali.EN  Smith.     Price  50  cts. 

Professor  Smith  discusses  the  relation  of  tnonej'  to  industrial  society,  the  two  concep- 
tions of  a  standard  of  value  and  the  unstability  of  gold  as  a  coninioditj'.  He  then  shows 
the  advantages  and  disadvantages  of  a  composite  gold  and  silver  standard,  and  advocates 
the  adoption  of  a  multiple  money  standard.  Under  this  plan  a  considerable  number  of 
leading  commodities  are  combined  together  in  the  ratio  of  their  importance  and  form 
the  permanent  standard  of  value,  which  standard  would  be  practically  invariable. 

The  Standard  of  Deferred  Payments.  By  Prof.  Edw.  A.  Ross.  New  edi- 
tion.    Price  15  cents. 

Pennsylvania  Paper  Currency.     By  Dr.  C.  W.  Macfarlane.     Price  50  cts. 

A  documentary  and  statistical  study  of  the  early  experience  of  Pennsylvania  in  issu- 
ing paper  money.  The  Pennsylvania  system  of  putting  out  money  on  loans  based  on 
landed  or  other  security,  received  long  ago  a  commendatory  notice  from  Adam  Smith, 
By  patient  research  among  old  records,  Dr.  Macfarlane  has  been  able  to  fully  trace  the 
history  of  this  interesting  experiment  in  currency.  The  es.say  thus  calls  attention  to 
some  aspects  of  the  money  problem  which  cannot  fail  to  be  of  interest  in  the  present 
era  of  discussion. 

RAILWAYS. 

Some  Observations  on  Railway  Pooling.  By  Hon.  MARTIN  A.  Knapp. 
Price  25  cents. 

The  purposes  of  railway  pools  are  here  pointed  out,  and  the  double-facedness  of  the 
Inter-State  Commerce  Law  clearly  exhibited.  Designed  to  prevent  discrimination,  it 
also  makes  railway  pools  illegal,  and  thus  deprives  the  companies  of  the  weapon  with 
which  they  could  themselves  combat  discrimination.  With  proper  legal  restrictions, 
Mr.  Knapp  believes  that  pools  should  be  permitted  and  hopes  from  such  permission  a 
fuller  realisation  of  the  purposes  of  the  Inter-State  Commerce  Act. 

BELGIUM. 

The  Constitution  of  the  Kingdom  of  Belgium.  Translated  and  supplied 
with  an  historical  introduction  and  notes  by  Prof.  John  Martin  Vin- 
cent.    Price  50  cents. 

Also  issued  in  this  series  the  Constitution  of  France,  of  Ital}',  of  Prussia, 
of  Mexico,  and  of  Colombia.     Price  50  cents  each. 

Neiu  and  complete  list  of  publicatiojis  on  application. 


American    Academy    of  Political    and  Social  Science, 
Station  B.  Philadelphia,  U.  S.  A. 


THE  CITIZEN, 

PUBLISHED    MONTHLY, 

By  the  Anierica7i  Society  for  the  Extensio7i  of  University  Teaching 


TREATING   OF 

PUBLIC  EDUCATION 

—  BY  — 

Schools,  Libraries, 

University  Extension  Teaching, 

Public  Health  and  Convenience, 

Conditions  of  Living, 
Civic  Education, 
Literature,  Art,  and  Science. 


A  very  large  number  of  scholars,  drawn  from  leading  universities  and 
colleges,  lectiire  in  University  Bxtension  courses.  The  cooperation  of  the 
Society's  Lecturers  and  Staif  should  give  THE  CITIZEN  a  unique  value. 

THE  EDITORIAL  DEPARTMENT  touc'ies  upon  topics  of  current  in- 
terest, falling  within  the  province  of  the  journal. 

THE  BOOK  REVIEWS  and  BOOK  NOTES  are  carefully  prepared, 

A  SPECIAL  DEPARTMENT  will  give  information  about  University  Ex- 
tension throughout  the  world. 


Rates — One  Number  lo  cts.    For  one  year  $i.oo,  postpaid. 


Advertising  rates  furnished  upon  application. 
Address  communications  to 

TME   CITIZEN, 
III  South  15th  Street,  Philadelphia. 


Revue  Politique  et  Parlementaire 

no,  Rue  de  l'Universite;. 


Directeur  :   Marcel  FOURNIER. 


Abonnement  Annuel.— Un  an:  23  fr. ;  Colonies  et  Union 
Postale :  30  fr.  ;  le  I<J°  :  3  fr. 

I,es  abonnements  parteut  de  Janvier  ou  de  Juillet. 

A.    COLIN    et  Cie,    5,    RUE   DE  ME:zIE:rES,— PARIS. 


SOMMAIRE  »U  N"  25— JUILLET 

I.  L'ESPRIT  DU  BUDGET  :  I^ES  IMpOts  ET  LES  REVENUS— Maurice  Block, 
de  I'lnstitut. 

II.  LES  CAISSES  DES  E;C0I^ES  et  I,EUR  situation  Legale.    Beurdeley, 
Maire  du  Vlll«  Arr'. 

III.  I,ES  .^LECTIONS  D'ESPAGNE.    Lefevre-Pontalis,  de  I'lnstitut. 

IV.  LE  TARIF  LEGAI^  DES  NOTAIRES.    A.  Douarche. 

V.  LES  PROGRES  DE  L' ASSURANCE  SUR  LA  VIE.    E.  Rochetin. 

VI.  LA  NOMINATION  DES  INSTITUTEURS.    A.  Albert-Petit. 

VII.  LE  MORCELLEMENT  DES  VALEURS  MOBILIEIRES  :  les  Salaires  ;  la  Part 
DU  Capital  et  du  Travail.    A.  Neymarck. 

VIII.   VARIETJSs,  notes,  voyages  et  DOCUMENTS  : 

\°  II  y  a  Trente  Ans  :  V  Occupation  de  Francfo7'i  par  les  Pmssiens  in  1866. 

A.  Raffalovich,  de  I'lnstitut. 
2°  P.-J.  Proudhon.  Ch.  de  Lariviere. 
3°  Souverainetk  du  Peuple  et  Gouvernemejit.    Th.  Ferneuil. 

IX.  REVUES  DES  PRINCIPALES  QUESTIONS  POLITIQUES  ET  SOCIALES  : 
Revue  des  Questions  Agricoles.    D.  Zolla. 

X.  LA  VIE  POLITIQUE  ET  PARLEMENTAIRE  A  L'fiTRANGER  : 
1°  Danemark.     Carstensen,  M"  du  Landsthing. 
2°  Ilalie.     L.  LuzzATTi,  M"  du  Pari'  Italien. 

XI.  LA  VIE  POLITIQUE  ET  PARLEMENTAIRE  EN  FRANCE  : 

1°  La  Politique  Exterieure  du  Mois.     Fr.  de  Pressense. 
2°  Chronique  Politique  Intirieure.    Felix  Roussel. 
3°  La  Vie  Parlementaire.    *  *  * 

XII.  CHRONOLOGIE  POLITIQUE  E;TRANGERE  ET  FRAN^AISE.    XXX. 

XIII.  BIBLIOGRAPHIE. 


Gioraale  Degli  Economisti 

RIVISTA  MENSILE  DEGLI  INTERESSI  ITALIANl 

ROMA 

Via  Naz^ionale,  87 


Abbonamento  annuo  Italia :  L.  30,  Estero  L.  35  -  Numero  separate  L.  3 


Sommario  del  Fascicolo  del  1°  Luglio,   1896 

I,  lya  situazione  del  mercato  monetario.     (X.) 

II.  La  base  agronomica  della  teoria  della  rendita  {Contiiitia). 
(G.  Valenti.) 

III.  I  dazi  fiscal!  e  i  consumi.     (Aldo  Contento.) 

IV.  La  circolazione  in  Italia— Difetti  e  rimedi.     (L.  Sbroja- 

vacca.) 

V.  Previdenza :  La  questione  dell'indebito  aggravio  alle  Casse 

di  risparmio  per  le  spese   di   vigilanza   portata   alia 
Camera.     (C.  Bottoni.) 

VI.  Cronaca:  Giustizia  italiana— II  discorso  del  sindaco  di 

Marsiglia— Dialoghi  morali.     (V.  Pareto.) 


THE  NEW  WORLD. 


A  Quarterly  Review  of  Religion,  Ethics  and  Theology. 

(200  pp.,  8vo.  :  issued  the  first  of  March,  June,  September  and  December.) 


EDITORIAL  BOARD  : 

Professors  C.  C.  Everett,  and  C.  H.  Toy,  of  Harvard  University  ;   President  Orello 

Cone,  of  Buchtel  College,  and  Prof.  N.  P.  Oilman,  (the  Managing  Editor,  to  be 

addressed  at  Meadville,  Pa.). 


"  There  is  always  something  good  to  read,  because  there  is  aways  earnest  thinking  in 
the  New  World  which  is  the  quarterly  organ  of  "reverent  breadth  "  in  American  re- 
ligious thought Altogether  the  New  World  is  a  periodical  which  deserves 

nuich  attention.     There  is  hardly  its  equivalent  on  this  side  of  the  Atlantic." 

The  Spectator  (London). 

Contents  of  No.   XVI,  December,  1895. 


Tendencies  of  Thought  in  Modern  Judaism. 
David  Philipson. 
The  Miracles  of  Jesus  in  the  Synoptic  Gos- 
pels. Albert  Reville. 
The  Anabaptists.  W.  E.  Griffis. 
The  Pseudo-Athanasian  Augustinianism. 

Levi  L-  Paine. 


Tito  Melema.  Julia  H.  Gulliver. 

Popular  Protestant  Controversy. 

C.  C.  Starbuck. 
Local  Cults  in  Homer. 

Arthur  Fairbanks. 
The  Nomadic  Ideal  in  the  Old  Testament. 
Karl  Budde. 


Contents  of  No.   XVII,  March,   1895. 


Octavius  Brooks  Frothingham. 

Thomas  Wentworth  Higginson. 
Miracles  and  Christian  Faith. 

John  E.  Russell. 
Thomas  Henry  Huxley. 

John  W.  Chadwick. 
The  Religion  of  the  Manchu  Tartars. 

C.  DE  Harlez. 


Tendencies  in  Penologj'. 

Samuel  J.  Barrows. 
Paul's  Doctrine  of  the  Atonement. 

C.  C.  Everett. 
Leibnitz  and  Protestant  Theologj'. 

John  W^atson. 
The  Preprophetic  Religion  of  Israel. 

C.  H.  Toy. 


Contents  of  No.  XVIII,  June,  1896. 


Cardinal  Manning,  St.  George  Mivart. 
International  Arbitration,  John  B.  Moore. 
Limits  of  the  Doctrine  of  Evolution, 

George  H.  Howison. 
Matthew  Arnold's  Letters,  Milton  Reed. 
New  England  Trinitarianism, 

Levi  L.  Paine 


The  Minister  and  Social  Problems, 

John  W.  Day. 
Las  Casas  and  Democracy, 

Charles  C.  Starbuck 
Mr.  Balfour  and  his  Critics,  T.  R.  Slicer. 
The  Will  to  Believe,  William  James. 


Single  Number,  75  cts.;  3s.    Yearly  Subscription,  $3.00  ;  12s. 


BOSTON  AND  NEW  YORK: 

HOUGHTON,  MIFFI^IN  &  CO.,  Publishers. 

LONDON  :    GAY  &  BIRD,  Bedford  St. 


Studies  in  History,  Economics  and  Public  Law, 

—  EDITED   BY  — 

THE  UNIVERSITY  FACUI.TY  OF  POIvlTlCAL  SCIENCE 
OF  COLUMBIA  COIvIvEGE. 

Numbers  marked  thus  *  are  not  sold  separately. 

VOIvUMB  I. 

I.  The  Divorce  Probi,em  :    A  Study  in  Staiistics.     By  Walter  F. 

Willcox,  Ph.D.     Price  50  ceuts* 

II.  History  of  Tariff  Administration  in  the  United  States,  from 

CoLONiAi,  Times  to  the  McKini^ey  Administration  Bii,i,.    By 
John  Dean  Goss,  Ph.D.     Price,  50  cents.* 
III.  History  of  Municipai,  Land  Ownership  on  Manhattan  Island. 
By  George  Ashton  Black,  Ph.D.     Price,  50  cents.* 

IV.  Financiai,  History  of  Massachusetts.    By  Charles  H.  J.  Douglas, 
Ph.D.     Price,  |i.oo. 

VOLUME  11. 

I.  The  Economics  of  the  Russian  Vii,i.age.     By  Isaac  H.  Hourwich, 

Ph.D.     Price,  $1.00. 
II.  Bankruptcy  :  A  Study  in  Comparative  Legisi^ation.     By  Samtiel 
W.  Dunscomb,  Jr.,  Ph.D.     Price,  75  cents.* 

III.  Speciai.  Assessments  :  A  Study  in  Municipai,  Finance.    By  Victor 

Rosewater,  Ph.D.     Price,  75  cents.* 

VOLUME  III. 

I.  History  of  Ei<ECTions  in  the  American  Coi^onies.     By  Cortlandt 
F.  Bishop,  Ph.D.     Price,  I1.50  ;  bound,  |2.oo. 

II.  The  Commercial  Policy  of  England  toward  the  American 

Colonies      By  George  Louis  Beer,  A.M.,     Price,  |i.oo. 

VOLUME   IV. 

I.  Financial  History  of  Virginia.     By  W.  Z.  Ripley,  Ph.D.     Price, 
75  cents. 

II.  The  Inheritance  Tax.     By  Max  West,  Ph.D.     Price,  75  cents. 
III.  History  of  Taxation  in  Vermont.     By  F.  A.  Wood,  Ph.D.     Price, 

75  cents. 

VOLUME  V. 

I.  Double  Taxation  in  the  United  States.      By  Francis  Walker, 

Ph.D.     Price,  75  cents. 
II.  Separation    of   Governmental   Powers.     By   William    Bondy, 
LL.B.,  Ph.D.     Price,  $1.00. 

III.  Municipal  Government  in  Michigan  and  Ohio.     By  Delos  F.  Wil- 

cox, Ph.D.     Price,  |i.oo. 


For  further  particulars  apply  to 

Prof.  Edwin  R.  A.  Seligman,  Columbia  College, 

or  to  The  Macmillan  Company,  New  York. 


Librarie  GuillauminetCie.,  Rue  Richelieu  14. — PARIS. 


Journal  des  Economistes 

REVUE    MENSUEI.LE 

De  la  Science  Bconomique  et  de  la  Statistique 

CINQUANTE-CINQUIEME  ANNEE. 


Redacteur  en  chef:   G.  de  MOLINARI, 

Correspondant  de  I'lnstitut. 


Sotnmaire  dii  No.  de   yidti  1896. 

Le  Socialisme  en  1896. — Les  rapports  du  capital  et  du  travail  aux  Etats-Unis. — 
Mouvement  scientifique  et  industriel. — Revue  de  rAcademie  des  sciences  morales 
et  politiqnes. — Un  Etat  mis  en  actions. — Le  socialisme  municipal  en  Angleterre. — 
L' Association  allemande  pour  la  liberie  commerciale. — Animaux  et  vers  primes. — 
Bulletin. — Society  d'Economie  politique  (stance  du  5  Juin  1896)  Discussion:  De 
I'Etat  de  I'enseignement  economique  en  France. — Comptes  rendus. — Chronique 
dconomique  et  Bulletin  bibliographique. 

Sommaire  du  No.  de  yiiillet  1896. 

Un  devoir  social. — La  veritable  situation  des  Soci^tes  frangaises  de  secours  mu- 
tuels. — Mouvement  colonial. — Revue  des  principales  publications  economiques  de 
I'etranger. —  Une  operation  commerciale  au  XVIII.  si^cle. —  Bulletin. —  Sociele 
d'Economie  politique  (s(§ance  du  6  Juillet  1896)  Discussion :  De  la  definition  de 
I'Economie  politique. — Comptes  rendus. — Chronique  economique  et  Bulletin  Biblio- 
graphique. 


Conditious  de  rabonuement ; 

France  un  an,  36  fr. 
Union  postale,  38  fr. 
Un  numero,  3  fr.  50. 


PUBLICATIONS  OF  THE  UNIVERSITY  OF  PENNSYLVANIA. 

Political  Economy  and  Public  Law  Series. 


Simon  N.  Patten,  Ph.D.,  Editor. 


VOLUME  I. 


No.  1. — Wharton  School  Annals  of  Political  Science.     Out  of  print. 
No.  2. — Anti-Rent  Agitation  in  New  York.     Prof.  E.  P.  Cheyney.     Price, 
50  cents. 

No.  3. — G-round  Rents  in  Philadelphia.  E.  P.  Allinson  and  Boies  Pen- 
rose, of  the  Philadelphia  Bar.     Price,  25  cents. 

No.  4. — Consumption  of  "Wealth.     Prof.  S.  N.  Patten.     Price,  50  cents. 

No.  5. — Prison  Statistics  of  the  U.  S.  for  1888.  Prof.  Roland  P.  Falk- 
NER.      Price,  25  cents. 

No.  6. — Rational  Principles  of  Taxation.  Prof.  S.  N.  Patten.  Price,  50 
cents. 

No.  7. — Federal  Constitution  of  Germany,  -with  Historical  Introduc- 
tion.    Translated  by  Prof.  E.  J.  James.     Price,  50  cents. 

No.  8. — Federal  Constitution  of  Switzerland.  Translated  by  Prof.  E.  J. 
James.     Price,  50  cents. 

Price  of  Nos.  2  to  Sin  One  Order,  $2.40. 
VOLUME  II. 

No.  9.— Our  Sheep  and  the  Tariff.     William  Draper  Lewis,  Ph.D.     Price, 

cloth,  $2.00;    paper,  ^1.25. 

VOLUME  III. 

No.  10. — The  German  Bundesrath.  Prof.  James  Harvey  Robinson.  Price, 
75  cents. 

No.  11.— The  Theory  of  Dynamic  Economics.     Prof.  Simon  N.  Patten, 

Price,  $1.00. 

VOLUME  IV. 

No.  12. — The  Referendum  in  America.  Dr.  Ellis  P.  Oberholtzer.  Price, 
$1.50. 

Price  of  Nos.  2  to  12  in  One  Order,  $6.00. 


PUBLICATIONS  OF  THE  UNIVERSITY  OF  PENNSYLVANIA. 


Wharton  School  Studies  in  Politics  and  Economics. 

This  baries  consists  of  monographs  by  the  students  of  the  Wharton  School  of  Finance 

and  Economy. 

No.  1. — The  Recent  Development  of  American  Industries.     By  the  Class 
OF  '91.     Price,  50  cents;  cloth,  $1.00. 

No.  2.— The   City   Government   of  Philadelphia.      By  the  Class  of  '93. 
Price,  cloth,  $1.50. 


LIBRttRY  OF  CONGRESS 


0  013  495  301  9    # 
PUBLICATIONS  OF  THE  AMERICAN  ECONOMIC  ASSOCIATION. 


No. 

I. 

No. 

2. 

No. 

3. 

No. 

4- 

No. 

5. 

No 

5. 

MONOGRAPHS. 

VOLUr^E  I. 

No.  I.     Report  of  the  Organization  of  the  American  Economic  Association.     B)' 

Richard  T.  Ely,  Ph.D.,  Secretary.     Price 50  cents. 
Nos.  2  and  3.     The  Relation  of  the  Modern  Municipality  to  the  Gas  Supply.     By 

Eiimnnd  J.  James,  Ph.D.     Price  y^  cents. 
No.  4.     Co-operation  in  a  Western  City.     By  Albert  Shaw,  Ph.D.     Price  7^  ceiits. 
No.  5.     Co-operation  in  New  England.     By  Edward  W.  Bemis,  Ph.D.     Price  ^j 

cents. 
No.  5.     Relation  of  the  State  to  Industrial  AcTtion.     By  Henry  C.   Adams,   Ph.D. 

Price  7S  cents. 

VOLUME  II. 

Three  Phases  of  Co-operation  in  the  West.     By  Amos  G.  Warner,  Ph.D. 

Price  js  cents. 
Historical  Sketch  of  the  Finances  of  Pennsylvania.     By  T.  K.  Worthing- 

ton,  Ph.D.     Price  "75  cents. 
The  Railway  Question.     By  Edmund  J.  James,  Ph.D.     Price  75  cents. 
The  Early  History  of  the  English  Woolen  Industry.     By  W.  J.  Ashley. 

M.A.     Price 'J5  ce7its. 
Two  Chapters  on  the  Mediaeval  Guilds  of  England.     By  Edwin  R.  A.  vSe- 

ligman,  Pli.D.     Price  75  cents. 
The  Relation  of  Modern  Municipalities  to  Quasi- Public  Works.     By  PI. 

C.  Adams,  George  W.  Knight,  Davis  R.  Dewe}^,  Charles  Moore,  Frank 

J.  Goodiiow  and  Arthur  Yager.     Price  75  cents. 

VOLUME  III. 

No.  I.     Three  Papers  Read  at  Meeting  in  Boston:   "  Statistics  in  Colleges,"  by 

Carroll  D.  Wright;    "Sociology  and  Political  Economy,"  by  F.  H. 

Giddings  ;  "The  Legal-Tender  Decisions,"  by  E.  J.  James.     Price  75 

cents. 
No.  2.     Capital  and  its  Earnings.     By  John  B.  Clark,  A.M.     Price  75  cents. 
No.  3  consists  of  three  parts:  "The  Manual  Laboring  Class,"  by  General  F.  A. 

Walker;    "Mine  Labor  in  the  Hocking  Valley,"  by  E-  W.  Bemis, 

Ph.D.  ;  "Report  of  the  Second  Annual  Meeting,"  by  Richard  T.  Ely, 

Secretary..     Price  75  cents. 
Nos.  4  and  5.     Statistics   and   Economics.     By   Richmond   Mayo-Smith,    A.M. 

Price  $1.00. 
No.  6.     The  Stability  of  Prices.     By  Simon  N.  Patten,  Ph.D.     Price  73  cents. 

VOLUME  IV. 

No.  I.  Contributions  to  the  Wages  Question:  "The  Theory  of  Wages,"  by 
Stuart  Wood,  Ph.D.  ;  "  Possibility  of  a  Scientific  Law  of  Wages,"  by 
John  B.  Clark,  A.M.     Price  75  cents. 

No.  2.     Socialism  in   England.     By  Sidney  Webb,  LL-B.     Price  75  cents. 

No.  3.  Road  Legislation  for  the  American  State.  By  Jeremiah  W.  Jenks,  Ph.D. 
Price  75  cents. 

No.  4.  Report  of  the  Proceedings  of  Third  Annual  Meeting  of  the  American  Eco- 
nomic Association,  bj'  Richard  T.  Ely,  Secretary  ;  with  addresses  by 
Dr.  William  Pepper  and  Gen.  F.  A.  Walker.     Price  75  cents. 

No.  5.  Three  Papers  Read  at  Third  Annual  Meeting:  "  Malthus  and  Ricardo," 
by  S.  N.  Patten;  "The  Study  of  Statistics,"  by  D.  R.  Dewey,  and 
"  Analysis  in  Political  Economy,"  by  W.  W.  Folwell.     Price  75  cents. 

No.  6.     An  Honest  Dollar.     By  President  E.  Benjamin  Andrews.     Price  75  cents.